Welfare Magnet Hypothesis, Fiscal Burden, and Immigration Skill Selectivity

Date01 April 2015
Published date01 April 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12092
AuthorAssaf Razin,Jackline Wahba
Scand. J. of Economics 117(2), 369–402, 2015
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12092
Welfare Magnet Hypothesis, Fiscal Burden,
and Immigration Skill Selectivity
Assaf Razin
Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853, USA
ar256@cornell.edu
Jackline Wahba
University of Southampton, Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK
j.wahba@soton.ac.uk
Abstract
In this paper, we investigate the effect of welfare state generosity on the difference between
skilled and unskilled migration rates, and the role of mobility restriction in shaping this
effect. We utilize the free labor movement within the European Union plus Norway and
Switzerland (EUR) and the restricted movement from outside the EUR in order to compare
the free-migration regime to the restricted-migration regime. We find strong support for the
magnet hypothesis under the free-migration regime, and the fiscal burden hypothesis under
the restricted-migration regime, even after controlling for differences in educational quality
and returns to skills in source and host countries.
Keywords: European Union; migration; migration regimes; social benefits
JEL classification:H50; J24; J61
I. Introduction
In this paper, we revisit the social magnet hypothesis in international mi-
gration. We investigate the effect of the generosity of the welfare state in
attracting international migrants. We look specifically at the skill composi-
tion of migration patterns, highlighting the difference between skilled and
unskilled migration rates. The novelty of the paper is in looking at the role
of labor mobility restrictions in shaping the effect of the welfare state on
migration. In a free-migration regime, the effect on the skill composition
is expected to be negative. However, in a restricted migration regime, there
might be an opposite effect, because voters will prefer selective migration
policies favoring skilled migrants who tend to be net contributors to the
fiscal system.
We acknowledge financial support from the NORFACE research programme on Migration
in Europe – Social, Economic, Cultural, and Policy Dynamics. We would also like to thank
Michael Kearns for excellent research assistance.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2014.
370 Welfare generosity and immigration skill selectivity
Tab le 1 . Immigration and aggregate social spending
Country of immigration Low educationaHigh educationaSocial expenditureb
Austria 47.5 12.7 26.01
Belgium 65.7 18.3 25.97
Denmark 44.8 17.3 27.08
Finland 48.7 23.8 28.95
France 74.6 16.4 27.59
Germany 65.9 21.8 25.84
Greece 44.5 15.0 17.49
Ireland 13.6 41.1 14.95
Italy 52.9 15.4 21.55
Netherlands 50.2 22.0 23.44
Norway 22.0 28.7 23.10
Portugal 59.7 18.6 15.95
Spain 28.7 18.5 21.15
Sweden 34.1 25.7 31.75
Switzerland 54.9 18.6 17.09
UK 34.1 34.9 18.42
Average EUR 46.4 21.8 22.94
Australia 35.3 40.3 15.68
Canada 29.6 58.8 18.69
USA 37.9 42.7 14.80
Average AUS/CAN/US 34.3 47.3 16.39
Source:aDocquier and Marfouk (2006); bOECD, Social Expenditure Database (SOCX).
Notes: Low education and high education are given as percent of total immigration in 2000. Social expenditure
is given as percent of GDP (average 1990–2000).
Public debate on immigration has increasingly focused on its effects on
the welfare state, amid concerns that immigrants are a fiscal burden. For
example, the average aggregate social spending as a percentage of gross
domestic product (GDP) for the 14 core European Union (EU14) coun-
tries (i.e., Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece,
Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and UK), plus
Norway and Switzerland (hereafter EUR), between 1990 and 2000, was
around 23 percent, compared to around 15 percent in the US, 19 percent
in Canada, and 16 percent in Australia. An interesting differential charac-
teristic of immigration between the EUR and US/Canada/Australia is the
higher relative skill composition of immigrants in the latter countries (see
Tab le 1 ). 1At f irst glance, this suggests that countries that have generous
welfare systems also have relatively more unskilled immigrants (i.e., wel-
fare state generosity acts as a magnet for unskilled migrants). However, the
skill composition of immigrants depends on many factors, and in particular
on the policy regime (i.e., whether migration is free or restricted). In other
1Docquier et al. (2012) classify host countries into five main groups based on their im-
migration policies. They argue that Europe has low restrictiveness in immigration policies,
while Western offshoots (US, Canada, and Australia) are more skill-selective.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2014.
A. Razin and J. Wahba 371
words, the generosity of the welfare state might affect the skill composi-
tion of immigrants differently, depending on which immigration policy is
adopted. The generosity of the welfare state determines the self-selection
of potential migrants (supply-side mechanism) and the immigration policy
in the destination country (demand-side mechanism). In this paper, we take
advantage of heterogeneous bilateral immigration policies to identify and
quantify these two mechanisms. We investigate how the skill composition
of migration patterns differs between free- and restricted-migration regimes.
We test how the generosity of the welfare state affects the skill composition
of immigrants across these policy regimes.
There has been large body of research on welfare migration, although
with mixed results.2For example, Borjas (1999), Enchautegui (1997), and
McKinnish (2007) for the US and De Giorgi and Pellizzari (2006) for Eu-
rope3show how the welfare-state generosity works effectively as a magnet
to migrants. However, Levine and Zimmerman (1999) show that welfare
benefits have little effect on the probability of households headed by fe-
males (the recipients of the benefits) to relocate in the US. Also, Gelbach
(2004) finds strong evidence of welfare migration in 1980, but less in
1990, for the US. However, none of these studies controls for migration
regime.4Studies of migration between states within the US can help only
by providing evidence of a free-migration regime. However, studies that
employ samples confined to the policy-controlled migration regime, but
at the same time employ a model of the migrants’ choice of whether to
migrate and to which country, are evidently problematic. In this case, the
estimates convey little information about the migrants’ choices – and hence
about the welfare state as a magnet to unskilled migrants – but do give
some information on the migration policy choices of the host country. Fi-
nally, studies that refer to both migration regimes without controlling for
them are problematic because they do not disentangle migration policies in
the host countries from the individual migrant’s migration choices in the
source countries.
We use 14 core EU countries (old member states) plus Norway and
Switzerland to study empirically the policy-regime differential effect of the
generosity of the welfare state on the skill composition of migration rates.
Freedom of movement and the ability to reside and work anywhere within
2See Brueckner (2000) for a review of this body of literature.
3See also Khoudour-Cast´
eras (2008) who has studied emigration from 19th century Europe.
He finds that the social insurance legislation, adopted by Bismarck in the 1880s, reduced
the incentives of risk-averse Germans to emigrate. He estimates that in the absence of social
insurance, the German emigration rate from 1886 to 1913 would have been more than double
its actual level.
4Two exceptions are the unpublished paper by Cohen and Razin (2009), which we follow
and extend, and a very recent paper by Giulietti et al. (2013).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2014.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT