Segregation in Friendship Networks

AuthorYves Zenou,Joan de Martí
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12178
Published date01 July 2017
Date01 July 2017
Scand. J. of Economics 119(3), 656–708, 2017
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12178
Segregation in Friendship Networks
Joan de Mart´
ı
Pompeu Fabra University, 08005 Barcelona, Spain
joan.demarti@upf.edu
Yves Zenou
Monash University, Caulfield, VIC 3145, Australia
yves.zenou@monash.edu
Abstract
We analyze a network-formation model where agents belong to different communities. Both
individual benefits and costs depend on direct as well as indirect connections. Benefits of an
indirect connection decrease with distance in the network, while the cost of a link depends on
the type of agents involved. Two agents from the same community always face a low linking
cost, while the cost of forming a relationship between two agents from different communities
diminishes with the rate of exposure of each of them to the other community. We find that
socialization among the same type of agent can be weak even if the cost of maintaining links
within one’s own type is very low. Our model also suggests that policies aimed at reducing
segregation are socially desirable only if they reduce the within-community cost differential
by a sufficiently large amount.
Keywords: Homophily; segregation; social networks; social norms
JEL classification:J15; Z13
I. Introduction
In social and economic contexts, individuals generally have relevant at-
tributes, such as ethnicity, gender, age, education, income, etc., and these
attributes are often related to their interaction patterns. Are individuals
more likely to be linked to others who have similar characteristics? This
We are grateful to two anonymous referees for very helpful comments. We also thank the
participants of the 13th Coalition Theory Network Workshop, of the seminars at IFN, IIES,
and Duke University, in particular, Andrea Galeotti, Guillaume Haeringer, Rachel Kranton,
and Karl Schlag for helpful comments, and we thank Willemien Kets for a thorough dis-
cussion. J. de Marti gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministry
of Education, through the project SEJ2006-09993/ECON and a Juan de la Cierva fellow-
ship (co-financed by the European Social Fund), from the Spanish Ministry of Science and
Innovation through grant ECO2011-28965, from the Comissionat per a Universitats i Re-
cerca del Departament d’Innovaci´
o, Universitats i Empresa de la Generalitat de Catalunya
through Beatriu de Pin´
os 2009 BP-A 00116 postdoctoral grant, and from Barcelona GSE and
the Government of Catalonia. Y. Zenou (also affiliated with IFN) gratefully acknowledges
financial support from the French National Research Agency grant ANR-13-JSH1-0009-01.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.
J. de M ar t´
ı and Y. Zenou 657
Fig. 1. Distribution of black students (left) and white students (right) byshare of same-race
friends in integrated schools [Colour figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
is a phenomenon known as homophily, and it refers to the fairly pervasive
observation in working with social networks that having similar character-
istics is often a strong and significant predictor of two individuals being
connected (McPherson et al., 2001). This means that social networks can,
and often do, exhibit strong segregation patterns. Segregation can occur be-
cause of the decisions of the people involved and/or by forces that affect the
ways in which they meet and have opportunities to interact (Currarini et al.,
2009, 2010; Tarbush and Teytelboym, 2012). Clearly, capturing homophily
requires one to model, or at least explicitly account for, characteristics of
nodes that exhibit a dimension of heterogeneity across the population.
The aim of this paper is to develop a network-formation model where
agents are heterogeneous in some observable characteristics (such as eth-
nicity), which imply different interaction costs between communities, and
where homophily behavior and segregation emerge in equilibrium.
Consider, for example, Figure 1, taken from Patacchini and Zenou
(2016), which depicts a friendship network among US high-school students
(using data from the National Longitudinal Study of Adolescent to Adult
Health, Add Health). It turns out that the (self-reported) friendships are
strongly related to ethnicity, with students of the same ethnicity being
significantly more likely to be connected to each other than students of
different ethnicities. To be more precise, Patacchini and Zenou (2016) use
the homophily index Hiof individual iproposed by Coleman (1958) to
analyze the exposure of individuals of white and black ethnicity to own
and other ethnicities. If the homophily index Hiof a student iis equal
to 0, this means that the percentage of same-race friends of this individual
equals the share of same-race students in the school. Negative values of
the index imply an underexposure to same-race students, while positive
values imply an overexposure to same-race students compared to the mean.
Figure 1 displays their results for mixed schools (i.e., schools with a
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.
658 Segregation in friendship networks
percentage of black and white students between 35 and 75 percent). Most
of the white students have white friends as roughly 40 percent of them are
associated with values of the homophily index greater than 0.4, denoting
a clear deviation from the assumption of random choice of friends by
race. Black students appear to be more heterogeneous in their choice
of friends than white students. The clear bimodality in the distribution
(corresponding to values of Hibetween 0.6 and 0.8 and between 0.6
and 0.8) reveals that there are, mainly, two types of black students: those
who have mostly white friends and those choosing mostly black friends.1
In this paper, we propose a network-formation model that can explain the
socialization patterns observed in Figure 1. For this, we consider a finite
population of individuals composed of two different communities. These
two communities are categorized according to some exogenous factor such
as, for example, their gender, race, or ethnic and cultural traits. Individuals
decide with whom they want to form a link, according to a utility function
that weights the costs and benefits of each connection. This results in a
network of relationships where a link between two different individuals
represents a friendship relationship. The utility of each individual depends
on the geometry of this friendship network.
To model the benefits and costs of a given network, we consider a varia-
tion of the connections model introduced by Jackson and Wolinsky (1996),
a workhorse model in the analysis of strategic network formation.2From
the standard connections model, we keep the property that an individual
benefits from their direct and indirect connections, and that this benef it
decays with distance in the network. This can be interpreted as positive
externalities derived from information transmission (of trends and fashion
for adolescents, of job offers for workers, etc.). However, in the standard
connections model, each link is equally costly, irrespective of the pair of
agents that is connected. We depart from this assumption as follows.
Consider the case where communities are defined according to ethnicity,
which might entail differences in language and social norms. When
two individuals of different communities interact, they might initially
experience a disutility because of the attachment to their original culture.
This discomfort can, however, be mitigated if individuals are frequently
exposed to the other community. Indeed, when someone spends time
1Marmaros and Sacerdote (2006) and Patacchini et al. (2015) show that the main determi-
nants of friendship formation are geographical proximity and race. Also, using administrative
data and information from Facebook.com, Mayer and Puller (2008) find that race is strongly
related to social ties, even after controlling for a variety of measures of socio-economic
background, ability, and college activities.
2See Goyal (2007), Jackson (2008), de Mart´
ı and Zenou (2011), Jackson and Zenou (2015),
and Jackson et al. (2017) for overviews of the growing body of literature on social and
economic networks.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT