Prices or Quantities Can Dominate Banking and Borrowing*

Published date01 April 2020
Date01 April 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12351
AuthorMartin L. Weitzman
Scand. J. of Economics 122(2), 437–463, 2020
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12351
Prices or Quantities Can Dominate Banking
and Borrowing*
Martin L. Weitzman
Harvard University,Cambridge, MA 02138, USA
Abstract
The possibility of intertemporal banking and borrowing of tradable permits is often viewed as
tilting the various policy debates about optimal pollution control instruments towards favoring
such time-flexible quantities. This paper showsthat this view can be misleading, at least for the
simplest dynamic extension of the original “prices versus quantities” information structure. The
model of this paper allows firms to know and act upon the realization of uncertain future costs
two full periods ahead of the regulators. Forany given circumstance, the paper shows that either
a fixed price or a fixed quantity is superior in expected welfare to time-flexible banking and
borrowing. Furthermore, the standard original formula for the comparative advantage of prices
over quantities contains sufficient information to completely characterize the regulatory role of
intertemporal banking and borrowing. The logic and implications of these results are analyzed
and discussed.
Keywords: Banking and borrowing; climate change; pollution; prices; prices versus quantities;
quantities; regulatory instruments
JEL classification:Q50; Q51; Q52; Q54; Q58
I. Introduction
Choosing the best instrument for controlling pollution has been a long-
standing central issue in environmental economics. This paper is primarily
concerned with the theory of environmental policy in terms of the basic
theoretical foundations of the instrument choice issue among the three
alternatives of fixed prices, fixed quantities, and time-flexible quantities
from intertemporal banking and borrowing.1
*I am indebted to the following people for their helpful and constructive comments (without
implicating them in errors, omissions, or interpretations): Reyer Gerlagh, Kenneth Gillingham,
Ben Groom, Garth Heutel, Ryan Kellogg, Frank Krysiak, Derek Lemoine, Jing Li, Jussi
Lintunen, Ian MacKenzie, Gilbert Metcalf, Guy Meunier, Ian Parry, Cedric Philibert, Simon
Quemin, Philippe Quirion, Mar Reguant, TillRequate, Richard Revesz, Andrew Schein, Richard
Schmalansee, Joseph Shapiro, Robert Stavins, Jean Tirole,Yi-Ming Wei, and three anonymous
referees.
Marty Weitzmanpassed away after the final version of this manuscript was accepted. Marty was
a deeply original thinker who will be greatly missed by the profession.
1I sprinkle in some comments on “practicality” throughout the paper, but the main focus is on
the pure economics of instrument choice. Thus, the broader dimensions of real-world political,
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.
438 Prices or quantities can dominate banking and borrowing
Pollution is a negative externality. Pigou (1920) introduced and
subsequently popularized the central concept of placing a price charge on
pollution (now called a “Pigouvian tax”) as an efficient way to correct
a pollution externality. This Pigouvian-tax approach dominated economic
thinking about the pollution externality problem for about the next half-
century.
Dales (1968) introduced the idea of creating property rights in the
form of tradable pollution permits (also called “allowances”) as an efficient
alternative to a Pigouvian tax. Montgomery (1972) proved rigorously the
formal equivalence between a price on pollution emissions and a dual
quantity representing the total allotment of tradable permits. Henceforth, it
became widely accepted that there is a fundamental isomorphism between
a Pigouvian tax on pollution and the total quantity of allotted caps in a
cap-and-trade system that ends up with all permits trading at the same
competitive equilibrium market price as the Pigouvian tax. For every given
Pigouvian tax, there is a total quantity of tradable permits allotted whose
competitive equilibrium market price equals the Pigouvian tax. And for
every given total quantity of tradable permits allotted, there is a competitive
equilibrium market price that would yield the same result if it were imposed
as a Pigouvian tax. Thus far, all of the analysis took place in a deterministic
context where everything was known with certainty.
Weitzman (1974) showed that with uncertainty in cost and benefit
functions there is no longer an isomorphism between price and quantity
instruments. The key distinction under uncertainty is that setting a fixed
price stabilizes marginal cost while leaving the total quantity variable,
whereas setting a fixed total quantity of tradable permits stabilizes
the total quantity while leaving the price (or marginal cost) variable.
The question then becomes, Which instrument is better under which
circumstances?
In his paper “Prices vs. Quantities” (Weitzman, 1974), Weitzman derived
a relatively simple formula for the “comparative advantage of prices over
quantities”, denoted in the paper as Δ. The sign of Δdepends on the
relative slopes of the marginal abatement-cost curve and the marginal
abatement-benefit curve. The sign of Δis positive (prices are favored over
quantities) when the marginal benefit curve is flatter than the marginal cost
curve. Conversely, the sign of Δis negative (quantities are preferred over
ideological,legal, social, historical, administrative, motivational, informational, timing, lobbying,
monitoring and enforcing considerations, or any other issues that are not purely economic, are
beyond the scope of this paper.For a balanced and overarching discussion of both theoretical and
practical issues involved in choosing between carbon taxesand a cap-and-trade system, see the
review article of Goulder and Schein (2013) and the many references cited therein.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT