Life Expectancy Heterogeneity and the Political Support for Collective Annuities

AuthorHelmuth Cremer,Philippe Donder
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12153
Published date01 July 2016
Date01 July 2016
Scand. J. of Economics 118(3), 594–615, 2016
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12153
Life Expectancy Heterogeneity and the
Political Support for Collective Annuities
Helmuth Cremer
Toulouse School of Economics, FR-31015 Toulouse, France
helmuth.cremer@tse-fr.eu
Philippe De Donder
Toulouse School of Economics, FR-31015 Toulouse, France
philippe.dedonder@tse-fr.eu
Abstract
Individuals, differing in productivity and life expectancy, vote over the size and type of a
collective annuity. Its type is represented by the fraction of the contributive (Bismarckian)
component (based on the worker’s past earnings) as opposed to the non-contributive (Bev-
eridgean) part (based on average contribution). The equilibrium collective annuity is either
a large mostly Bismarckian program, a smaller pure Beveridgean one (in accordance with
empirical evidence), or nil. A larger correlation between longevity and productivity, or a
larger average life expectancy, both make the equilibrium collective annuity program more
Beveridgean, although at the expense of its size.
Keywords: Collective annuity; generosity; Kramer–Shepsle structure-induced equilibrium;
longevity; pay-as-you-go pensions; redistributiveness
JEL classification:D78; H55
I. Introduction
A sizeable body of literature deals with the political determination of the
characteristics of a public pay-as-you-go pension system. The influential
paper by Browning (1975) assumed that the only heterogeneity between
voters is their age. Subsequent papers (such as Casamatta et al., 2000a)
have enriched this approach by assuming that agents also differ in income
or in productivity. This richer set of individual traits has allowed these
papers to study the determination of both the size of the pension system
IDEI, University of Toulouse and Institut universitaire de France.
GREMAQ-CNRS and IDEI.
A previous version of this paper has circulated under the title “Longevity, Annuities and
the Political Support for Public Pensions”. We thank P. Belan, B. Heijdra, and L. Meijdam
for their comments. We also thank the editor and the referees for their constructive and
extremely helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from the Chaire March´
edes
risques et cr´
eation de valeur of the FdR/SCOR and from Netspar through a research grant
is gratefully acknowledged.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
H. Cremer and P. De Donder 595
and of its redistributiveness across income levels. As for the latter, the
literature (surveyed by Galasso and Profeta, 2002) has contrasted so-called
Bismarckian systems, where the pension benefit is proportional to the
individual contribution, with Beveridgean systems, where the benefit is
based on the average contribution.
The main stylized fact in this domain is that Bismarckian systems tend
to be larger (as measured by either the contribution rate or the share of pub-
lic pensions in GDP) than Beveridgean systems; see Table 1 in Casamatta
et al. (2000b), and also Disney (2004) or Conde-Ruiz and Profeta (2007).
Very few papers have tried to explain this correlation. Both Casamatta
et al. (2000b) and Koethenbuerger et al.(2008) study the determination by
the median voter of the size of the pension system as a function of the
system’s type, measured by the (exogenous) relative importance of the con-
tributive component, dubbed the Bismarckian parameter. Casamatta et al.
(2000b) assume exogenous wage income and obtain an ambiguous impact
of the Bismarckian parameter on the equilibrium size of the pension sys-
tem. Koethenbuerger et al. (2008) introduce endogenous labor supply, and
find that larger labor supply distortions, generated by the flat-rate Bev-
eridgean pension system versus the earnings-related Bismarckian system,
can explain why more redistributive systems are smaller. Conde-Ruiz and
Profeta (2007) study the simultaneous determination of the size and type
of pension systems. In their model, agents differ in age and income, and
in ability to invest in the capital market. With only three income groups,
a small Beveridgean system is supported by low-income agents, who gain
from its redistributive feature, and high-income individuals, who seek to
minimize their tax contribution and to invest their resources in a private
scheme. Middle income individuals, instead, favor a large Bismarckian sys-
tem. The degree of inequality in earnings and the level of capital market
returns determine which type of equilibrium emerges.
An important dimension of heterogeneity among voters, that is, longevity,
which might play a critical role in the determination of the pension system,
is absent from these studies. It is well known empirically that people of the
same age differ in life expectancy. Moreover, life expectancy is positively
correlated with income or wealth, as shown by Deaton and Paxon (1999)
for the US, by Attanasio and Emerson (2001) for the UK, and by Reil-Held
(2000) for Germany. Average life expectancy has been increasing in most
countries for at least half a century. However, these increases have not
been shared equally everywhere. For instance, in the US, the average male
life expectancy at 65 has increased from 15 to 16.1 years between 1986
and 2006 for individuals in the bottom half of the earnings distribution,
but from 16.5 to 21.5 years in the top half of the earnings distribution
(Waldron, 2007). It is thus important to assess the impact of such variations
on pension programs.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT