Is a Policy of Free Movement of Workers Sustainable?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12163
AuthorTim Worrall,Pierre M. Picard
Published date01 October 2016
Date01 October 2016
Scand. J. of Economics 118(4), 718–754, 2016
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12163
Is a Policy of Free Movement of Workers
Sustainable?
Pierre M. Picard
University of Luxembourg, L-1511, Luxembourg
pierre.picard@uni.lu
Tim Worrall
University of Edinburgh, Edinburgh, EH8 9JT, UK
tim.worrall@ed.ac.uk
Abstract
In this paper, we study the costs and benefits of the adoption of a policy of free movement
of workers. For countries to agree on uncontrolled movements of workers, short-run costs
must be outweighed by the long-term benefits of better labor-market flexibility and income
smoothing. We show that such a policy is less likely to be adopted when workers are more
impatient and less risk-averse, when production technologies display stronger decreasing
returns, and when countries trade a significant share of their products.
Keywords: Labor-market flexibility; migration; sustainable plan
JEL classification:F22; J61
I. Introduction
Since its inception, the European Union (EU) has aimed at implementing
a policy of free movement of workers between member states (Article 45,
EU Lisbon Treaty). However, some EU member states have been reluctant
to implement this policy, implementing it in stages, applying different stan-
dards of implementation, or in some cases applying policies as restrictive
as for non-EU immigrants. Similar projects and difficulties have emerged
in other country associations such as the North American Free Trade Area
Also affiliated with CORE, Catholic University of Louvain, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium.
We thank two referees for many useful comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to
participants at the 2011 NORFACE Conference on migration and seminars at Erasmus Uni-
versity, Oxford University, and University Carlos III, and University of Lille for comments.
We are grateful to M. Beine, C. D´
etang-Dessendre, G. Fachini, A. Margherita, P. Neary, T.
Mueller, E. Toulemonde, and A. Venables for helpful comments and suggestions. The first
author gratefully acknowledges the support of the grant F2R-CRE-PUL-10EGQH, University
of Luxembourg. The second author gratefully acknowledges the support of the Hallsworth
Research Fellowship Fund at the University of Manchester. The usual caveats apply.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
P. M. Picard and T. Worrall 719
(NAFTA), in which the TN status currently allows the free movement of
workers only between the US and Canada. The main reason for this re-
luctance lies in the fear that inflows of migrant workers might depress
local labor-market conditions and lower the welfare of the host country’s
workers.1
It is not difficult to find evidence for why country associations might aim
for a policy of free movement of workers and fail to agree on it. Migration
offers large benefits to the immigrants (see, for example, Klein and Ventura,
2009; Clemens et al., 2010) but imposes short-run costs on local workers,
particularly the low-skilled ones (see, for example, Borjas, 2003). In this
paper, we consider the balance of short-term costs with long-term benefits,
and examine the decision of countries to open their borders and adopt
policies of unconditional and uncontrolled movements of workers. The
approach we adopt is similar to the literature on sustaining free trade
(see, for example, Bagwell and Staiger, 1990; Staiger and Bagwell, 1999;
Bagwell and Staiger, 2005; Grossman and Helpman, 1995).2We consider
a repeated model with a simple stochastic structure. To sustain a policy
of free movement of workers requires that no country finds it unilaterally
beneficial to breach the policy. As in the sustainable trade literature, we
suppose that a breach leads to reversion to repetition of a short-run Nash
equilibrium where labor migration is completely controlled. Each country
therefore weighs the short-run cost of immigration against the long-term
benefits, and the policy of free movement of workers is sustainable if, at
each date and state, the long-term benefits exceed the short-run costs for
each country.
To examine this issue, we consider a simple, two-country, dynamic model
where, under free movement of labor, workers freely choose their location
in each time period. Although our main aim is to consider the implications
of migration and trade together, we proceed in stages to develop the model.
Initially, we consider a model where immigration imposes a cost on locals
without specifying how these costs arise (Sections II and III). Taking the
source of this cost as given, we examine how it might be offset by a
long-run benefit stemming from a policy of free movement, in which
labor markets are integrated and workers (and their descendants) are able
to relocate to more productive countries, allowing them to smooth their
consumption. In considering these costs and benefits, it is important to take
1In 2005, the referenda rejecting the European Constitution by the Dutch and French publics
occurred in the context of the debate over the accession of Turkey to the EU. In 2011,
the fear of uncontrolled immigration waves has enticed France to threaten to suspend its
obligation to the EU freedom of movement (Schengen Treaty; see Waterfield, 2011).
2More generally, our approach relates to the discussion about sustainable government poli-
cies (see, for example, Chari and Kehoe, 1990; Acemoglu et al., 2010) and self-enforcing
insurance mechanisms (see, for example, Thomas and Worrall, 1988; Ligon et al., 2002).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
720 Is a policy of free movement of workers sustainable?
into account a possible externality created by free movement of labor. Free
movement will lead to equalization of utilities in equilibrium, but there is
no specific price for the migration decision. Migrants do not inter nalize the
effect of their move on the productivity and consumption of local workers.
If free movement creates a greater cost in the receiving country than gain
in the sending country, then reducing the extent of migration could increase
aggregate welfare: free movement leads to excessive agglomeration of labor
in the receiving country. However, if free movement creates a lower cost
in the receiving country than gain in the sending country, then increasing
the extent of migration could increase aggregate welfare: free movement
leads to under-agglomeration of labor in the receiving country. Under-
or excessive agglomeration decrease the long-run benefits of a policy of
free movement of labor. However, they have opposite effects in the short
run: excessive agglomeration increases the short-run costs while under-
agglomeration ameliorates the short-run costs.
It is therefore important to know more about the relative costs and
benefits of a policy of free movement of labor. We consider these costs and
benefits by more precisely specifying the model in Sections IV and V. In
Section IV, we examine a standard migration model without trade but with
productivity shocks. If production is iso-elastic, then there is no excessive
agglomeration. However, weaker congestion enhances countries’ incentives
to adopt a policy of free movement of workers, because it mitigates the
short-run costs of immigration. Similarly, stronger risk-aversion enhances
countries’ incentives to adopt such a policy because it raises the benefits
from income smoothing that the policy brings. We also show how labor-
market frictions, in terms of minimum wages, affect the sustainability of
policies of free movement of labor.
Finally, in Section V, we discuss the costs and benefits of adopting
a policy of free movement of workers in the presence of international
trade. In the Hecksher–Ohlin benchmark, factor prices are equalized across
countries and workers have no incentives to migrate. To discuss migration
issues, we therefore depart from this model and present a simple Ricardo–
Viner trade model with production of both tradeable and non-tradeable
goods. Because there is a non-tradeable good and differences in technolo-
gies across countries, factor price equalization does not hold and there will
still be an incentive for migration. As has been recognized by Davis and
Weinstein (2002) (see also, Felbermayr and Kohler, 2007), in the presence
of trade, migration induces a terms-of-trade effect. With both tradeable and
non-tradeable goods, the change in the terms of trade caused by migration
has an adverse effect on the relative import prices and the consumption
basket of domestic workers. However, this terms-of-trade effect also at-
tenuates the impact of productivity shocks on consumption and reduces
workers’ incentives to move. We show that the presence of trade leads
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT