How Important Are Scale Effects for Growth When Knowledge Is a Public Good?

AuthorFernando Sánchez‐Losada
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12273
Date01 April 2019
Published date01 April 2019
Scand. J. of Economics 121(2), 763–782, 2019
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12273
How Important Are Scale Effects for Growth
When Knowledge Is a Public Good?*
Fernando S´anchez-Losada
University of Barcelona, 08034 Barcelona, Spain
fernando.sanchezlosada@ub.edu
Abstract
In this paper, byproposing an R&D accumulation law for an economy with an expanding number
of firms, I seek to reconcile the following three facts: the positiverelationship between the fraction
of income allocated to R&D expenditureand g rowth;the positive relationship between the number
of firms and total factor productivity growth; and knowledge as a non-rival and non-excludable
good. There are scale effects because of the public nature of knowledge, but the economy also
grows in the absence of population growth. I find that population growth explains one-fifth of
market income growth but only one-sixteenth of efficient income growth.
Keywords: Efficientgrowth; market growth; population growth
JEL classification:O30; O40; O41
I. R&D-Variety Growth Models and Scale Effects
In recent years, there has been some discussion as to which of the
following growth models provides a better explanation of technological
progress: R&D-variety growth models or Schumpeterian models. In R&D-
based models of growth (see Jones, 1995), a positive increase in R&D
resources is required to maintain sustained growth, given the assumption of
diminishing returns to knowledge. Hence, a rising supply of researchers is
needed. This implies that growth is explained exclusively by scale effects
and, therefore, an economy with zero population growth experiences zero
income growth. In contrast, in Schumpeterian models (see Dinopoulos and
Thompson, 1998), there is a positive relation between the fraction of income
allocated to R&D expenditure and economic growth. This implies growth
without scale effects.
*I acknowledge useful comments received from one anonymous referee, the participants at the
UB Macro Internal Seminar, Daniel Cardona, David Cuberes, Patricio Garc´ıa-M´ınguez, Vahagn
Jerbashian, Charles I. Jones, Xavier Raurich, andAusias Rib ´o, and wouldespecially like to thank
Edgar Cruz for his time. I am grateful for financial support from the Ministerio de Econom´ıa y
Competitividad and Fondo Europeo de Desarrollo Regional through grant ECO2015-66701-R
(MINECO/FEDER, UE) and from the Government of Catalonia through grant 2014SGR493.
Affiliated with the Center for Research in Welfare Economics (CREB) and the Barcelona
Economics Analysis Team(BEAT).
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.
764 Scale effects and knowledge as a public good
In principle, the empirical evidence supports Schumpeterian models
(see Zachariadis, 2003; Madsen, 2008). However, these papers suggest
that this conclusion could also be reached by the diminishing returns to
knowledge assumed in the R&D-variety growth models and, as such, they
support the findings of Madsen (2007) and Venturini (2012). While the
former concludes that R&D might be characterized by constant returns to
scale, the latter reports that knowledge production functions based on the
expansion of variety overlook some relevant institutional and policy factors.
Indeed, developed countries during the 20th century were characterized by
a negative relationship between population growth and economic growth
(see Galor and Weil, 2000). To reconcile the R&D-variety growth model
and this circumstance, Strulik et al. (2013) introduce the Beckerian child
quantity–quality trade-off.1
However, for growth, the importance of scale effects in their own right
as well as via agglomeration economies has been broadly documented. For
example, Nickell (1996) shows that an increase in the number of firms is
associated with a higher rate of total factor productivity (TFP) growth.
Likewise, ´
Alvarez-Pel´aez and Groth (2005) highlight the importance of
the returns to specialization for growth. Ciccone and Hall (1996) find
that doubling employment density increases average labor productivity
by 6 percent, whereas Davis et al. (2014) estimate that the impact of
local agglomeration on the growth rate is about 10 percent. Therefore,
because competition increases as the number of firms grows, competition
drives growth, as Nickell (1996) has shown empirically. In other words,
an increased number of competitors in the same industry is positively
correlated with TFP growth. Thus, an R&D-variety growth model should
at least explain a significant part of this growth.
It seems clear that because knowledge is non-rival and non-excludable,
population matters in the determination of growth. The rationale is that an
increase in population makes an increase in knowledge more likely, which
is to the benefit of the population. From an economic point of view, it is
therefore clear that as knowledge is a public good, endogenous growth
exhibits some kind of scale effects.2This positive correlation between
growth and technological advancement or knowledge, and population
growth, has been empirically shown in Kremer (1993) for the very long
run.
In this paper, I seek to reconcile these three facts (the positive
relationship between the fraction of income allocated to R&D expenditure
and growth; the positive relationship between the number of firms and
1The connection between growth, human capital, and the child quantity–quality trade-off had
previously been shown byZhang (1995) and Zhang and Zhang (2003), among many others.
2See Jones (1999) for an exhaustive reviewof this body of literature.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT