Heaven's Swing Door: Endogenous Skills, Migration Networks, and the Effectiveness of Quality‐Selective Immigration Policies

Published date01 April 2015
AuthorSimone Bertoli,Hillel Rapoport
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12095
Date01 April 2015
Scand. J. of Economics 117(2), 565–591, 2015
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12095
Heaven’s Swing Door: Endogenous Skills,
Migration Networks, and the Effectiveness
of Quality-Selective Immigration Policies
Simone Bertoli
University of Auvergne, CERDI, FR-63000 Clermont-Ferrand, France
simone.bertoli@udamail.fr
Hillel Rapoport
Paris School of Economics, CES, FR-75647 Paris, France
hillel.rapoport@univ-paris1.fr
Abstract
A growing number of OECD countries are leaning toward the adoption of selective immi-
gration policies, which are expected to raise the quality (or education level) of migrants.
This view neglects two important dynamic effects: the role of migration networks, which
could reduce the quality of migrants, and the responsiveness of education decisions to the
prospect of migration. We propose a model of self-selection into migration with endogenous
education choices, which predicts that migration networks and the quality of migrants can
be positively associated when destination countries adopt sufficiently selective immigration
policies. Empirical evidence, presented as background motivation, suggests that this is indeed
the case.
Keywords: Brain drain; discrete choice models; migration; self-selection
JEL classification:F22; J61; O15
I. Introduction
A growing number of OECD countries are leaning toward adopting more
restrictive and increasingly quality-selective immigration policies, which
confer better chances of admission at destination to those applicants with
a higher level of education. This tendency is apparent from the gradual
introduction of points-based immigration systems, first in Canada in 1967,1
The authors are grateful to Slobodan Djajic, Aitor Lacuesta, and the participants at various
conferences and seminars for their comments. This research was supported by the Agence
Nationale de la Recherche of the French government through the program Investissements
d’avenir (ANR-10-LABX-14-01) and by the FERDI. The usual disclaimers apply.
1Education alone can provide an applicant with up to 25 out of the 67 points that are
currently necessary for admission into Canada (Bertoli et al., 2012), and its pivotal role in
shaping the chances of admission is magnified by its positive correlation with labor-market
experience (21 points) and language proficiency (24 points).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2014.
566 Endogenous skills, migration networks, and immigration policies
followed by Australia in 1989, New Zealand in 1991, and more recently
the UK in 2008. Elsewhere, immigration policies have also evolved towards
becoming more restrictive quantitatively and more selective qualitatively,
be it through the introduction of specific visa categories for highly skilled
professionals (e.g., the H1-B visa category in the US, or the European
“Blue Card” project currently in its infancy) or through the introduction
of biased selection criteria, making low-skill immigration more difficult
while at the same time encouraging permanent high-skill immigration (e.g.,
France’s short-lived “chosen immigration” reform of 2007).2
Observed migration flows are the result of the combined effect of self-
selection (i.e., size and skill composition of a given pool of candidate
immigrants) and out-selection (i.e., external selection among existing can-
didates) mechanisms. The underlying assumption behind quality-selective
immigration policies is that more selection will raise the average education
level of migrants. This makes perfect sense from a static standpoint, when
we regard the pool of applicants as given. Still, this pool evolves over
time as the migration process unfolds: migration networks tend to reduce
the moving costs (Massey et al., 1994; Carrington et al., 1996; Munshi,
2003; Kanbur and Rapoport, 2005), thus influencing the self-selection into
migration (McKenzie and Rapoport, 2010; Beine et al., 2011a; Bertoli,
2010a).
The cost-reducing effect of migration networks is best illustrated by
the “swing door” metaphor in the title of our paper: while the first mi-
grants to push the door will encounter the most resistance, their followers
will be able to enjoy the lower resistance of a swing door in movement.
The literature has established that this swing door effect is not neutral
with respect to the quality of migrants. McKenzie and Rapoport (2010)
find that the probability of (f irst-time) migration from Mexico to the US
increases with education up to relatively high education levels in commu-
nities with small networks (high migration costs). This is consistent with
positive self-selection and, conversely, with the fact that migration propen-
sities decrease with education in communities with large networks (low
migration costs), which is consistent with negative self-selection. A similar
result is obtained by Bertoli (2010a) from the analysis of Ecuadorian mi-
gration, while Beine et al. (2011a) provide evidence that larger networks
translate into more negative self-selection patterns using bilateral data from
2The decline in the level of education of immigrants (Borjas, 1999), with its possible
contribution to rising inequality and increased pressure on underprivileged segments of the
native population (Borjas et al., 2010), has prompted proposals to increase the degree of
selectivity of immigration policies (see, for instance, the specific proposals advanced by
Borjas, 1999); the immigration reform bill that was introduced in the US Senate in April
2013 contains a provision for the admission of 120,000 immigrants per fiscal year through
a merit-based system.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2014.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT