Financing of Firms, Labor Reallocation, and the Distributional Role of Monetary Policy*

Date01 April 2020
Published date01 April 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12354
Scand. J. of Economics 122(2), 790–823, 2020
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12354
Financing of Firms, Labor Reallocation, and
the Distributional Role of Monetary Policy*
Salem Abo-Zaid
University of Maryland-Baltimore County,Baltimore, MD 21250, USA
salem.abozaid@umbc.edu
Anastasia Zervou
University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX 78712, USA
zervoua@gmail.com
Abstract
We analyze monetary policy in a model with heterogeneous firms, where constrained firms
finance operations through external financing and unconstrained firms use internal funds. We
show that expansionary monetary policy increases the relative employment of constrained
firms, while positive productivity shocks increase that of unconstrained firms. Our results agree
with recent empirical findings, emphasizing the role of the monetary authority in reallocating
resources across sectors with different financing capabilities. We also show that if the relative
productivityof constrained firms is low, then expansionary monetary policy tilts resources towards
less productive firms, which decreases the effectiveness of the policy in stimulating aggregate
output.
Keywords: Firms’ financing; heterogeneous firms; labor reallocation; monetary policy
JEL classification:E32; E44; E52
I. Introduction
Firms are heterogeneous in terms of financing opportunities in that a large
share of them depend on borrowing to finance operations.1In addition,
empirical evidence shows that heterogeneous firms react differently to
economic shocks (Gertler and Gilchrist, 1994; Moscarini and Postel-Vinay,
2012; Chari et al., 2013; Fort etal., 2013; Kudlyak and Sanchez, 2017). With
this paper, we contribute to the existing body of literature by presenting
a simple model in order to study the implications of different financing
*Wethank Stephen Williamson, James Bullard, Charles Carlstrom, YiLiChien, Timothy Fuerst,
Francois Gourio, John Haltiwanger, FrancescoLippi, Vivien Lewis, Jonathan Meer, Christopher
Pissarides, Juan Sanchez, Jacek Suda, Christian Moser, Christian vom Lehn, RodrigoVelez, the
National Federation of Independent Business, and the participants at various conferences and
seminars.
1According to Rajan and Zingales (1998), more than 30 percent of the operation of US firms
depends on external finance.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.
S. Abo-Zaid and A. Zervou 791
schemes for the cyclical sensitivity of heterogeneous firms following
economic shocks, as well as to examine the relative redistributive power of
these shocks. Our quantitative exercise reveals responses that are consistent
with those in the data, and stresses the redistributive role of monetary policy
in shifting resources across firms that differ in the way that they finance
their operation.
Specifically, we construct a limited participation model with two types
of firms: constrained firms that need to borrow in advance in order to
operate, and unconstrained firms that operate using internal resources.
As a result, the cost of external financing drives changes in relative
employment across the two sectors. We use this model to study the
effects of monetary policy and productivity shocks on labor. We find that
expansionary monetary policy benefits constrained firms, as it decreases
the cost of borrowing and leads to a rise in their labor and production.
Importantly, while expansionary monetary policy also leads to a rise in the
labor and production of unconstrained firms, the allocation of labor tilts in
favor of the constrained firms. In this respect, not only is monetary policy
effective in stimulating aggregate economic activity but it also plays a great
role in the distribution of economic activity across sectors. However, this
redistributive role might have undesirable consequences; if the constrained
firms are less productive than the unconstrained firms, then expansionary
monetary policy tilts resources towards the less productive firms, making
monetary policy less effective in stimulating aggregate activity. This result
emphasizes the limitation of representative-firm models in assessing the
effectiveness of monetary policy.
Apropos of productivity shocks, our model suggests that a positive
shock induces an increase in the production of financially constrained and
financially unconstrained firms. Yet, the surge in economic activity leads
to an increase in the interest rate and, thus, benefits the unconstrained
firms more than the constrained firms. The relative employment of the
unconstrained firms rises, making the unconstrained firms more cyclical
following productivity shocks. In the baseline model, where we assume the
same productivity across firms, the effects of productivity shocks on the
allocation of labor across sectors is considerably smaller than the effects of
monetary policy disturbances. When we allow for higher productivity for the
unconstrained firms or a muted rise in the productivity of the constrained
firms (which could reflect a slower adoption of new production technologies
by small firms), then the effects of productivity shocks on the relative
employment of constrained and unconstrained firms are greatly magnified.
Yet, the response of relative employment to productivity innovations remains
weaker than its response to monetary policy shocks.
In order to relate our findings to the empirical literature on differential
behavior of firms over the cycle and following shocks, we conjecture
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.
792 Financing of firms and distributional role of monetary policy
that small firms, in terms of assets or employment size, and young firms
are more likely to be constrained compared with large/old firms.2Then,
we assume that small/young firms rely on external financing, and thus
are subject to the external financing premium. This assumption has its
foundation in previous empirical work. For example, by studying the
investment of US manufacturing firms, Fazzari etal. (1988) find that smaller
firms are more likely to be liquidity constrained. Gertler and Hubard (1988)
find that smaller firms rely heavily on intermediary credit while large firms
use more direct credit. More recently, Shourideh and Ariel (2017) find
that private firms finance externally roughly 80 percent of their investment
contrary to only 20 percent for larger, publicly traded firms. Haltiwanger
et al. (2013) have highlighted the importance of the age of a firm for
understanding why firms react differently to shocks. Adelino et al. (2017)
show that, compared with older firms, young firms are more likely to face
severe financing constraints, and that job creation by new firms is larger in
areas with better access to small business financing.
The heterogeneous responses of firms to economic shocks have been
well documented in the empirical literature. Using the dates of monetary
policy shocks given by Romer and Romer (1989), Gertler and Gilchrist
(1994) conclude that small firms (i.e., firms with low values of gross
nominal assets) react more than larger firms; they severely reduce their sales
and inventories and, thus, are more cyclical than larger firms after monetary
policy shocks. Chari et al. (2013) and Kudlyak and Sanchez (2017) verify
these findings for a longer time period. Assuming that interest rate shocks
in our model map on to the dates of monetary shocks given by Romer and
Romer (1989), then the results that are generated by our model align with
the empirical evidence on the effects of monetary policy disturbances on
heterogeneous firms.
Regarding productivity shocks, Chari et al. (2013) find that after
recession dates given by the National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER), large firms react more than small firms, thus reducing their sales
and inventories more. Kudlyak and Sanchez (2017) emphasize that this
effect holds also for the recent Great Recession. Moscarini and Postel-
Vinay (2012) find that large firms (in terms of employment) on net destroy
proportionally more jobs relative to small firms during a typical recession,
and that they create more jobs during a typical expansion. Our results
align with the above empirical findings if we consider positive (negative)
2While we do not explicitly model the size or age of firms, there are a few reasons behind our
assumption that small/young firms are more sensitive to the external financing premium. For
example, higher cash flows make it easier for larger firms to finance production internally. Also,
large/old firms that are traded can more easily raise capital internally.These effects are supported
by the discussion that follows concerning the empirical literature.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT