Endogenous Comparative Advantage*

Published date01 July 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12291
Date01 July 2019
Scand. J. of Economics 121(3), 1088–1124, 2019
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12291
Endogenous Comparative Advantage*
Andrea Moro
VanderbiltUniversity, Nashville TN 37235, USA
andrea@andreamoro.net
Peter Norman
University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill NC 27599, USA
normanp@email.unc.edu
Abstract
We develop a model of trade between identical countries. Workers endogenously acquire skills
that are imperfectly observed by firms; therefore, firms use aggregate country investment as the
prior when evaluatingworkers. This creates an informational externality interacting with general
equilibrium effects on each country’s skill premium.Asymmetric equilibria with comparative
advantages exist even when there is a unique equilibrium under autarky. Symmetric, no-trade
equilibria can be unstable under free trade. Welfareeffects are ambiguous: trade can be Pareto-
improving even if it leads to an equilibrium between rich and poor countries, with no special
advantage regarding country size.
Keywords: Human capital; reputation; specialization; trade
JEL classification:D62; D82; F11; O12
I. Introduction
In this paper, we develop a stylized model of international trade in which
a country can establish a reputation for having a high-quality labor force.
This provides new insights into the understanding of the causes of trade,
specialization, and inequality across countries.
A reputation for the high or low quality of a labor force can arise
when employers do not perfectly observe workers’ competencies and skills.
Workers acquire human capital not only through education and work
experience, but also through personal effort and investments that are not as
easily observable. We focus on this informational asymmetry, showing that
it can generate self-fulfilling differences in reputation across countries.
Research has shown that informational asymmetries of this kind are
empirically relevant. Farber and Gibbons (1996) and Altonji and Pierret
*It is nearly impossible tot hank everybodythat contributed comments and suggestions. We thank
them all, especially the anonymous associate editor and two referees. Support from NSF Grants
SES-0003520 and SES-0001717 is gratefully acknowledged.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
A. Moro and P. Norman 1089
(2001) first showed that employers’ learning is significant, supporting the
assumption that employers initially observe workers’ skills with noise.1
Recent literature confirms these results.2This suggests that there is
significant scope for the mechanism proposed in this paper to play a role
in determining workers’ wage distribution and their incentives to acquire
skills, and in sorting across industries.
Based on this evidence, we cannot dismiss the possibility that labor
market informational asymmetries might play a role in explaining, at least in
part, trade and specialization across countries. In this paper, we demonstrate
that they are sufficient to generate self-fulfilling cross-country differences
in reputation that imply human capital differences, trade, and specialization
between otherwise identical countries. There is arguably an incomplete
understanding of the patterns of trade and specialization observed in the
real world, which suggests that exploring alternative models could provide
new insights.3
In our model, technology has constant returns to scale, a country is
defined as a labor market, and international trade is frictionless. Countries
are symmetric in every respect, so the model always admits symmetric
equilibria that replicate autarky, without gainful trade. The only aspect of
the model that is non-standard is workers’ skill acquisition. We investigate
the conditions that generate equilibria with asymmetric country reputations
for skill investments, and we show the properties of such equilibria.
Workers can acquire skills at a cost that varies across workers. There are
two sectors demanding labor (i.e., a high-tech sector and a low-tech sector),
and skills increase productivity only in the high-tech sector. Incentives to
acquire skills are affected by an informational asymmetry: workers’ skills
are only observed by employers with noise, through a signal of productivity
that can be thought of as aggregating information provided by the worker’s
1In most of the literature, the identification of the main effect exploits panel data where workers
are observed over time. If employers imperfectly observe workers’ skills, but learn over time
through the observation of productivity signals, then as tenure increases, wages should become
more correlated with measures of productivity available to the researcher (typically, workers’
scores in aptitude tests).
2Inpar ticular,Lange (2007) measured the “speed” of employer learning, and found that, according
to the best estimates, it takes three years for an employer to reduce their expectation error to
50 percent of its initial value, and 26 years to reduce it to less than 10 percent of its initial
value. Note that median employee tenure is currently just above four years (January 2016;
see the US Bureau of Labor Statistics Economic News Release, Employee Tenure Summary,
https://www.bls.gov/news.release/tenure.toc.htm). See also Sch ¨onberg (2007), Pinkston (2009),
and Kahn and Lange (2014) who use US data, and Lesner (2018) whouses Danish data. Cor nwell
et al. (2017) use Brazilian data to show that variation in how employers perceive workers’race
significantly affects wages.
3A full empirical investigation of the model implications, which would require accounting for
(and separately identifying) other relevant factors, is outside the scope of this paper.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
1090 Endogenous comparative advantage
curriculum vitae, interviews, and observation in the workplace. A worker
without skills (hereafter referred to as an unqualified worker) can send a
good signal, but this is less likely than a qualified worker (i.e., a worker
with skills) sending a good signal.
Before observing the noisy signal, the prior probability of investment
is determined in each country by aggregate investment rates summarized
by the proportion of qualified workers. The probability of investment of
each worker is then computed using their signal, but it is also affected
by the prior. Hence, the actual proportion of qualified workers, together
with endogenous relative prices, determines incentives to invest. There is
no point in investing in skills if there are very few qualified workers in the
country, because firms interpret a good signal as most likely being noise
and the good signal raises the wage very little. Symmetrically, if almost all
workers invest, firms ignore bad signals as “bad luck”, and again there is
no point in investing as all workers receive high wages regardless of the
signal. Incentives to invest are at their highest at some intermediate level
of aggregate investment because this is when firms pay most attention to
the noisy signals.
Hence, starting from a relatively low level of investments, the value
to acquire human capital increases if the proportion of skilled workers
in the economy increases as the signal-to-noise ratio decreases. Working
against this, there are relative price effects that make the high-tech good
less valuable when its supply increases, but these effects are smaller
when countries trade than in autarky. Additionally, when skills increase
in one country, the incentives to acquire skills in the other country are
unambiguously reduced because of the price effects. Hence, an asymmetric
allocation of human capital and goods production can arise even if
countries are fundamentally identical. As far as we know, this is an
explanation of trade and specialization that is novel in the international
trade literature. What is crucial for this result is that the reputation for
having a qualified labor force is like a public good – operating within a
country regardless of its size.
While our mechanism is novel, there are some similarities with models
of agglomeration. Scale economies and network effects can also create
asymmetries between countries. However, these models usually assume
some exogenous differences that are being accentuated in equilibrium.
Moreover, in these models it is typically an advantage to have a large
domestic market, whereas in our model there is no systematic effect that
favors large countries. It is not the number, but the proportion of qualified
workers that is critical in generating the reputational externality. This is
because employers, when assessing workers, use the proportion of qualified
workers as their prior for human capital investment. A worker is more likely
to be qualified the higher their country’s proportion of qualified workers.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT