Empirical Evidence on the Relationship between Mobile Termination Rates and Firms' Profits

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12125
Published date01 January 2016
Date01 January 2016
Scand. J. of Economics 118(1), 129–149, 2016
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12125
Empirical Evidence on the Relationship
between Mobile Termination Rates and
Firms’ Profits
Kjetil Andersson
University of Agder, NO-4630 Kristiansand, Norway
kjetil.andersson@uia.no
Øystein Foros
NHH Norwegian School of Economics, NO-5045 Bergen, Norway
oystein.foros@nhh.no
Bjørn Hansen
Telenor, NO-1331 Fornebu, Norway
bjorn.hansen@telenor.com
Abstract
The theoretical literature on mobile termination rates (MTRs) is inconclusive on how the
level of MTRs affects overall consumer charges and firms’ profits. We show that when fir ms
offer bundles with fixed included usage – a tariff structure that has become more common
in recent years – an identical change in all MTRs does not affect firms’ retail prices or
profits. We use a panel dataset from saturated European markets to estimate the effect of
MTRs on mobile operators’ profits. As predicted by the theoretical model, we cannot reject
the fact that firms’ prof its are unaffected by an identical change in all MTRs.
Keywords: Competition; mobile communication markets; regulation
JEL classification:C23; L21; L51; L96
I. Introduction
When a telephony subscriber calls a subscriber on another mobile network,
the originating network operator pays a fee per minute to the terminating
mobile operator; this is called the mobile termination rate (MTR). Since
the mid-1990s, the levels of MTRs have been a topic for disputes, both
between market players and between market players and policy makers.1
There is a previous version of this paper (Andersson and Hansen, 2009). We are grateful
for helpful comments from Kjell Arne Brekke, Espen R. Moen, and seminar participants at
the Norwegian School of Management, NTNU, and the ZEW 2008 Conference on ICT.
1Armstrong and Wright (2009) note that the UK governmental reports on termination rates
aggregate to several thousand pages. Reductions in MTRs have also encountered many
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
130 Relationship between MTRs and firms’ profits
The European Commission wants to reduce the level of MTRs, the conjec-
ture being that firms have incentives to agree on high MTRs as a collusive
device.2
Theory predicts that a firm always has an incentive to unilaterally in-
crease its own termination rate. This arises from the competitive bottle-
neck problem. When consumers subscribe to only one mobile operator
(single-homing consumers), the operators have exclusive monopoly power
in providing termination (i.e., allowing subscribers on other networks to
call its customers). The competitive bottleneck problem is a general prob-
lem in two-sided markets where consumers are single-homing (Armstrong,
2006). For fixed-to-mobile calls, where fixed-line operators face restrictive
one-sided regulation of termination rates, mobile operators thus have an
incentive to raise termination rates (e.g., Armstrong and Wright, 2009).3
In contrast, for mobile-to-mobile calls, termination rates are often set
reciprocally. The theoretical literature is then inconclusive on how MTR
levels affect overall consumer charges and fir ms’ profits. The outcome
depends on the type of retail tariffs.4In the case of linear retail pricing with
no discrimination, based on whether the receiver of a call subscribes to the
same network as the caller (on-net calls) or a rival’s network (off-net calls),
Armstrong (1998) and Laffont et al. (1998a) show that firms might use
high MTRs as an instrument to soften competition by raising each other’s
marginal cost. However, linear tariffs (no other charges than per minute)
are rarely observed, and Laffont et al. (1998a) demonstrate that the profit
raising effect from increasing MTRs disappears when networks compete in
two-part tariffs. Any increase in termination revenues from higher MTRs
is passed on to consumers in the form of reduced subscription fees – a
so-called waterbed effect.5Gans and King (2001) show that if two-part
tariffs are combined with network-based discrimination (the call prices
reports from market players. See, for example, Frontier Economics (2008), a report prepared
for Deutsche Telekom, Orange, Telecom Italia, Telefonica, and Vodafone.
2Recently, there has been a change in the Commission’s approach. Previously, the level
of regulated MTRs was based on a principle of coverage of common and fixed costs
(e.g., Armstrong and Wright, 2009). The current approach is that MTRs should reflect the
incremental costs of providing termination services (European Commission, 2009).
3By the same token, in media markets, for example, a newspaper has exclusive market power
in delivering single-homing readers as eyeballs to advertisers (see Anderson and Coate, 2005,
for an influential contribution).
4Armstrong (2002) provides a comprehensive review of the early literature. Hoernig (2014)
and Armstrong and Wright (2009) synthesize and summarize the subsequent literature.
5Dessein (2003) and Hahn (2004) extend this basic model to allow for customer hetero-
geneity. They find that the profit neutrality result still holds when the networks compete in
menus of non-linear tariffs (as long as all customer groups participate in equilibrium).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT