Causal Effects of Paternity Leave on Children and Parents

AuthorLars J. Kirkebøen,Jon H. Fiva,Sara Cools
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12113
Published date01 July 2015
Date01 July 2015
Scand. J. of Economics 117(3), 801–828, 2015
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12113
Causal Effects of Paternity Leave on
Children and Parents
Sara Cools
BI Norwegian Business School, NO-0442 Oslo, Norway
sara.cools@bi.no
JonH.Fiva
BI Norwegian Business School, NO-0442 Oslo, Norway
jon.h.fiva@bi.no
Lars J. Kirkebøen
Statistics Norway, NO-0033 Oslo, Norway
kir@ssb.no
Abstract
Reserving a share of the parental leave period for fathers is considered necessary in order
to induce fathers to take leave, and to increase men’s participation in child-rearing. We
investigate how a parental leave reform directed towards fathers affected leave-taking, and,
in turn, children’s and parents’ long-term outcomes. A paternal leave quota greatly increases
the share of men taking paternity leave. We find evidence that children’s school performance
improves as a result, particularly in families where the father has higher education than
the mother. We find no evidence that paternity leave counters the traditional allocation of
parents’ labor supply.
Keywords: Child development; labor supply; parental leave
JEL classification:I21; J13; J22; J24
I. Introduction
Paternity leave is often discussed as a policy measure to encourage greater
gender equality, both in the family and in the labor market. Politicians and
policymakers in Northern Europe are strong believers that paternity leave
We are grateful to Tarjei Havnes, Timo Hener, John Kennes, Shelly Lundberg, Kalle Moene,
Magne Mogstad, Hessel Oosterbeek, Mari Rege, Marte Rønning, Uta Sch¨
onberg, Ingeborg
Solli, Katharina Wrohlich, several seminar participants, and the referees for helpful comments
and suggestions. This paper is part of the research activities at the Centre of Equality, Social
Organization, and Performance (ESOP) at the Department of Economics, University of Oslo.
ESOP is supported by the Research Council of Norway through its Centres of Excellence
funding scheme, project number 179552.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
802 Causal effects of paternity leave on children and parents
strengthens women’s position in the labor market, reduces the gender wage
gap, and promotes bonding between children and fathers.1
Wishing to alter traditional patterns of household specialization, politi-
cians provide incentives to increase men’s involvement in the home. Even a
few weeks of paternity leave, the argument goes, might result in substantial
changes in the longer run.2Thus, Finland, Iceland, Norway, and Sweden
have all reserved a share of the parental leave for fathers. Similar proposals
are also popular – though highly debated – in other European countries.3
In this paper, we investigate how paternity leave affects a broad range of
outcomes using Norwegian register data. To handle the selection problem
and to learn about the causal effects of paternity leave on children and
parents, we use two parental leave reforms, implemented in 1992 and 1993.
A main feature of the 1993 reform was the introduction of a four-week
paternal quota. This reform caused a drastic change in fathers’ leave-taking
behavior. To isolate the effect of the paternal leave, we contrast the 1993
reform with the 1992 reform, which did not contain a paternal quota, but
which otherwise was similar.
Fathers who took parental leave after the implementation of the 1993
reform typically spent four weeks at home with the child. In itself, this
might seem like too short a period to have much impact as the child grows
older. Yet, spending four weeks as the main caregiver of an infant – and
preparing for this period from the time the child is born – might set off a
different dynamic both between parents as caregivers, and between the fa-
ther and his child. First, in the framework of Becker (1985), small changes
in initial conditions can result in substantial changes in the household’s
time allocation in the long run. Second, as an early childhood interven-
tion, self-productivity and strategic complementarities could multiply the
investment made by the father in his child during these weeks (Cunha
and Heckman, 2007). Third, the paternal quota, typically taken when the
child is about ten months old, coincides with a critical stage in the child’s
attachment to primary caregivers (Bowlby, 1969). In sum, both economic
and psychological theory give us reason to expect that these four weeks
1These views are articulated in a series of white papers: Likestilling for Likelønn (Stort-
ingsmelding nr. 6 (2010–2011)) in Norway, and Reformerad F¨
or¨
aldraf¨
ors¨
akring – K¨
arlek,
Omv˚
ardnad, Trygghet (SOU 2005:73) in Sweden.
2“To strengthen the father’s role in his child’s life, it is important for him to participate
in childcare during the child’s first year. A portion of the parental leave period should
therefore be reserved for the father.” (From the Norwegian Government’s long-term program
for 1990–1993 (Stortingsmelding nr. 4), our translation.)
3Germany, for example, introduced in 2007 a two-month paternity quota intended to provide
incentives for parents to share home and market work equally (Entwurf eines Gesetz zur
Einf¨
uhrung des Elterngeldes, Deutscher Bundestag Drucksache 16/1989, 20.06.2006).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT