Authority and Incentives in Organizations

Published date01 April 2017
AuthorMatthias Kräkel
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12172
Date01 April 2017
Scand. J. of Economics 119(2), 295–311, 2017
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12172
Authority and Incentives in Organizations
Matthias Kr¨
akel
University of Bonn, DE-53113 Bonn, Germany
Abstract
I consider a corporation that consists of an owner, a manager, and two divisions. There
exist externalities between the divisions: if a division behaves cooperatively, its success
will increase the performance of the other division. The owner creates monetary effort
incentives and allocates decision authority over the divisions. I characterize how externalities
and benefits of control determine the corporation’s optimal organization. The introduction
of endogenous incentives changes the major findings of the existing literature, because then
concentrated delegation of authority over both divisions to one of the division heads will be
optimal if cooperation is important and divisions are difficult to incentivize.
Keywords: Centralization; contracts; decentralization; moral hazard
JEL classification:D21; D23; D86; L22
I. Introduction
Large corporations are usually organized as hierarchies and controlled by a
top manager (e.g., the CEO), who determines the strategy and exerts effort
that influences the performance of all organizational units at the lower
hierarchy levels. The major question then is how shall authority rights be
allocated between the manager and the organizational units to create the
best organizational structure? In this paper, I answer the question from an
incentive perspective.
In practice, strong cooperation between the different organizational units
is often crucial for the success of corporations.1For example, at the former
General Electric Co. small electric motors were produced by one organiza-
tional unit and transferred to other units that used the motors to produce
home appliances. Nowadays, General Electric is a conglomerate with inde-
pendent divisions, on the one hand, but also complementarities within single
divisions, on the other. Hewlett Packard consists of several largely indepen-
dent divisions, but because of strong technological interdependences among
its products it has to coordinate production and R&D activities. Likewise,
I would like to thank two anonymous referees, and the participants of the XIV Annual
Conference of the German Economic Association of Business Administration (GEABA), in
particular Christian Lukas, for helpful comments.
1The following examples refer to US corporations. However, similar observations also hold
for large corporations outside the US.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
296 Authority and incentives in organizations
Argyres (1995) refers to General Motors and IBM as prominent examples
of corporations that apply systems technologies, that is, technologies “for
which modification in one component requires significant adjustment in
other components, so that design coordination is necessary for innovation
at the systems level” (Argyres, 1995, p. 338).
The examples indicate that the divisions’ activities have to be coordi-
nated via the allocation of formal authority rights because otherwise the
whole organization runs the risk of a breakdown. There exists a wide spec-
trum of possible allocations of authority between the two polar cases of
decentralization and centralization. Under decentralization, each division
head receives authority over their own division, whereas under central-
ization the manager at the highest hierarchy level has authority over all
divisions. Prominent examples for these polar cases and their respective
success or failure are reported by Argyres (1995). He compares IBM and
General Motors, both facing coordination problems due to strong techno-
logical interdependences between their divisions. Argyres points out that
IBM successfully adopted a centralized organizational structure, although
this strategy led to distorted incentives. General Motors, on the contrary,
chose decentralization and failed. These findings are quite intuitive. They
show that decentralization might be beneficial for incentive reasons be-
cause divisions can be separately managed as profit centers, but for the
coordination of a firm’s activities, centralization is more appropriate.2
The design of organizational structure via allocation of authority typi-
cally triggers the behavior of the authorized decision maker (i.e., toward
either more selfish or more cooperative actions). In the case of decen-
tralization, each division head tends to selfishly focus on own division
profits. In the case of centralization, however, the manager at the top of
the hierarchy naturally cares greatly about cooperation between the divi-
sions. Decentralized General Motors and centralized IBM again offer good
examples for these behavioral patterns. As Argyres (1995) reports, no co-
operation took place between the division heads at General Motors, who
ignored possible synergies and made their procurement and applications
engineering decisions independently to minimize own costs. At IBM, how-
ever, potential intervention of corporate management made the divisions
behave cooperatively. For example, the Personal Systems Division volun-
tarily invested considerable time to achieve compatibility of its software
projects with other IBM projects, although this investment led to a delay
in completing own projects.
In this paper, I consider a stylized hierarchy with four players: the owner
of the corporation, who chooses optimal incentive contracts for the three
2See also the cases of Eastman Kodak and McKinsey, considered by Brickley et al. (2014,
chapter 9).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT