Are Larger Merger Synergies Bad News for Consumers? Endogenous Post‐Merger Internal Organization

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12303
AuthorDuarte Brito,Margarida Catalão‐Lopes
Published date01 October 2019
Date01 October 2019
Scand. J. of Economics 121(4), 1728–1756, 2019
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12303
Are Larger Merger Synergies Bad News for
Consumers? Endogenous Post-Merger
Internal Organization*
Duarte Brito
Universidade Novade Lisboa, 2829-516 Caparica, Portugal
dmb@fct.unl.pt
Margarida Catal˜ao-Lopes
Universidade de Lisboa, 1049-001 Lisboa, Portugal
mcatalao@tecnico.ulisboa.pt
Abstract
In this paper, we endogenize the post-merger internal organization of firms, considering two
alternative structures: multidivisional, in which separate divisions are kept, and traditional, with
cost synergies. Weanalyze when each structure occurs in equilibrium and how it affects welfare.
Weshow that higher synergies do not necessarily lead to higher consumer surplus: firms can opt
for a merger type that does not increase consumer surplus as much as the one that would occur
with lowersynergies. This highlights the importance of antitrust authorities basing their decisions
not just on the magnitude of eventual synergies but also on the post-merger organizationalfor m.
Keywords: Endogenous firm structure; mergers and acquisitions; multidivisional firms
JEL classification:L13; L22; L41
I. Introduction
The creation of divisions within a firm that results from a merger is an
interesting possibility. By keeping its divisions independent, and providing
its managers with the adequate incentives, the firm that results from the
merger can make full use of its structure to obtain a strategic advantage
over its rivals. Examples of firms operating several divisions are relatively
common in the hotel industry, in the tobacco market, in the matches market,
in the beer market, in the automobile industry, in broadcasting, in the airline
industry, and in the tissue market, among others.
This multidivisional form contrasts with the traditional full integration of
the merging parties. By keeping separate divisions in operation, the merged
*D. Brito acknowledges financial support from Funda¸aoparaaCiˆencia e a Tecnologia and
FEDER/COMPETE (UID/ECO/04007/2013).
Faculdade de Ciˆencias e Tecnologia.Also affiliated with CEFAGE-UE.
CEG-IST, Instituto Superior T´ecnico.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
D. Brito and M. Catal˜ao-Lopes 1729
firm might be unable to obtain some cost savings or synergies that are
usually associated with mergers. Farrell and Shapiro (2001) call synergies
the efficiencies that cannot be obtained unilaterally as they “require intimate
integration of the parties’ unique, hard-to-trade assets”, which can be harder
to obtain when divisions operate independently. Huck et al. (2004) also
mention that “[i]n contrast [to firms remaining as independent decision-
making units], cost advantages and increasing returns may suggest a fusion
of the merging firms to a single unit of production and decision-making.”
Thus, it is reasonable to assume that cost reductions or synergies are, at least
partially, foregone if the merged firm decides to operate several independent
divisions.
This means that, under some circumstances, the owners of a merged
firm face a trade-off and must make a choice: to operate as a single firm,
benefitting from some cost savings (traditional merger), or to operate with
several independent divisions (multidivisional merger). At the expense of
cost savings, the latter type of merger enables an internal organization
structure that increases the set of strategies available to the firm, providing
it with a different type of advantage with respect to its rivals.
In this paper, we make this decision endogenous: firms choose the post-
merger internal organization that yields the highest post-merger profit, from
the set of those that would be approved by a competition authority. In terms
of set-up, we assume that firms sell a homogeneous product and compete
in a Cournot way with constant marginal costs. As for mergers, we bring
together two alternative ways of modeling mergers that we borrow from
the literature discussed in the following section.
In addition to characterizing when each type of merger will take place
and how it will affect welfare, we also obtain some interesting results.
We show that the existence of higher potential cost synergies does not
necessarily imply higher consumer surplus in equilibrium. In the presence
of only one type of merger, this would be impossible. However, by allowing
for different types of mergers, higher cost savings might make firms choose
a different type of merger (the “wrong” type of merger in the consumers’
perspective), which does not increase consumer surplus as much as the one
that would be proposed under lower cost savings. In other words, firms
choose traditional mergers too often, which is inefficient, and the policy
recommendation that can be derived from this result is that authorities
that follow a consumer surplus standard should be more demanding in
terms of the magnitude of cost savings required for traditional merger
approval, when multidivisional mergers are deemed possible. Otherwise,
their decisions can lead to suboptimal results in terms of consumer surplus.
The intuition for this new insight for merger policy is simple. In our setting,
the multidivisional merger is more profitable and yields a higher consumer
surplus than the alternative traditional merger, provided that synergies are
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT