Unobserved Heterogeneity, Exit Rates, and Re‐Employment Wages

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12173
AuthorPedro Gomes,Javier Fernández‐Blanco
Published date01 April 2017
Date01 April 2017
Scand. J. of Economics 119(2), 375–404, 2017
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12173
Unobserved Heterogeneity, Exit Rates,
and Re-Employment Wages
Javier Fern´
andez-Blanco
Universitat Aut`
onoma de Barcelona and Barcelona GSE, 08193 Bellaterra, Spain
javier.fernandez@uab.cat
Pedro Gomes
Universidad Carlos III, 28903 Getafe, Spain
pgomes@eco.uc3m.es
Abstract
Exit rates from unemployment and re-employment wages decline over a period of unemploy-
ment, after controlling for worker observable characteristics. We study the role of unobserved
heterogeneity in an economy with asymmetric information and directed search. We show that
the unique equilibrium is separating and that skilled workers have more job opportunities
and higher wages. The composition of the unemployed varies with the duration of unem-
ployment, so average exit rates and wages fall with time. The separating equilibrium relies
on performance-related pay schemes and the ability of firms to commit to renting an input
that is complementary to worker skills.
Keywords: Asymmetric information; directed search; unemployment duration
JEL classification:J01; J21; J42; J64
I. Introduction
It is well documented that exit rates from unemployment and wages from
re-employment decline with the duration of unemployment, after control-
ling for worker observable characteristics. Since Lancaster (1979) and
Heckman and Singer (1984), the empirical literature has emphasized that
ex ante unobserved heterogeneity (or sorting) accounts for a large part of
the decline in exit rates. According to this explanation, workers differ in
terms of certain time-invariant characteristics, which are unobservable to
the econometrician and potentially to recruiting firms, and this translates
into differences in employment prospects. As a result, the average exit
rates fall with the duration of unemployment because of variation in the
composition of the unemployed. Despite its quantitative importance, very
A previous version was circulated under the title “Composition effects in the labor market”.
We thank Jan Eeckhout, Bel´
en Jerez, Claudio Michelacci, and Edgar Preugschat for their
valuable feedback. J. Fern´
andez-Blanco acknowledges financial support from the Spanish
Ministry of Science and Technology under Grant Nos. ECO2010-19357 and EC02013-46395.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.
376 Unobserved heterogeneity, exit rates, and re-employment wages
little theoretical research has been performed to address this explanation.
Lockwood (1991) was a remarkable early exception, but re-employment
wages were assumed to be constant in this study. Gonzalez and Shi (2010)
and Fern´
andez-Blanco and Preugschat (2014) provided theoretical explana-
tions of the duration dynamics of one of these two variables, but they were
not conclusive about the other variable. Furthermore, the explanation of
sorting in these three studies was somewhat circular because worker het-
erogeneity was modeled based on exogenous differences in the likelihood
of obtaining a job.
We consider a sorting mechanism based on productivity differences
across workers, which is consistent with falling exit rates and wages. We
analyze a frictional labor market in which workers are informed privately
about skills and search is directed. These skills are treated as abilities that
recruiters cannot grasp either from a CV or an interview, but they can be
assessed on the job. An adverse selection problem arises if unskilled work-
ers crowd out skilled applicants. Thus, firms design self-selection schemes
in equilibrium to separate worker types in different submarkets. The sort-
ing mechanism relies on two ingredients. First, in the absence of screening
devices, performance-contingent compensation plans are a central feature
of these sorting schemes, as noted in the literature regarding personnel eco-
nomics (e.g., Lazear and Shaw, 2007). In our study, performance-related
pay is derived from the assumption that rents generated by a job–worker
pair are split according to some exogenous rule. Second, firms have the
ability to commit to renting an input that is complementary in terms of
production to the skills of workers. We refer to that production input as
capital or machine quality.1These linear renting costs together with the
concavity of the production technology mean that the surplus generated by
a firm–worker pair is hump-shaped in capital.
Firms ar e ex ante identical. In equilibrium, a mass of firms commits
to renting the machine quality that maximizes the surplus derived from a
match with an unskilled worker. Likewise, a continuum of firms commits
to machines with higher quality because they and skilled workers anticipate
that their match would produce a larger surplus, and thus higher wages and
profits. Higher expected profits attract a relatively higher number of fir ms,
so they are associated with higher exit rates from unemployment. Therefore,
the average exit rate from unemployment and the average re-employment
wage fall with duration because of the variation in the composition of the
unemployment pool.
1We interpret machine quality in a generic manner as any set of inputs that are comple-
mentary in terms of production to unobservable skills. For example, this set could contain
co-workers, physical capital, and software (to the extent that the documented complementari-
ties with the observable characteristics of the labor input, mainly education, can be extended
to the unobservable characteristics), or intermediate goods.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT