Understanding the Determination of Severance Pay: Mandates, Bargaining, and Unions*

AuthorMarkus Poschke,Samuel Danthine,Stéphane Auray
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12367
Date01 July 2020
Published date01 July 2020
Scand. J. of Economics 122(3), 1073–1111, 2020
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12367
Understanding the Determination of
Severance Pay: Mandates, Bargaining,
and Unions*
St´ephane Auray
CREST-ENSAI,FR-35712 Bruz Cedex, France
stephane.auray@ensai.fr
Samuel Danthine
ENSAI, FR-35712 Bruz Cedex, France
danthine.samuel@gmail.com
Markus Poschke
McGill University,Montr ´eal, QC, H3A 2T7, Canada
markus.poschke@mcgill.ca
Abstract
A substantial share of severancepayments derives from private contracts or collectiveagreements.
In this paper, we study the determination of these payments. We analyze joint bargaining
over wages and severance payments in a search-and-matching model with risk-averse workers.
Individualbargaining results in levels of severance pay that providefull insurance, but also depend
on unemployment benefits and job-finding rates. Unions also choose full insurance. Because
their higher wage demands reduce job creation, this requires higher severancepay. Severance pay
observed in eight European countries, to which we calibrate the model, lies between predictions
from the bargaining and union scenarios.
Keywords: Bargaining; severance pay; unemploymentinsurance; unions
JEL classification:E24; J32; J33; J64; J65
I. Introduction
Job termination can have important welfare consequences for workers. As
a result, arrangements for severance pay exist in many countries around the
*We would like to thank Nicolaas Vermandel (Laga) for providing us with some data about
severance pay measures. We also thank the participants at various seminars and conferences
for helpful comments, and we are especially grateful to Bruno Decreuse, our discussant at the
workshop on “Unemployment, Wage Inequality and Labor Market Policy” in Konstanz. SD
gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovaci´on under
project ECO2011-29355, and from Junta de Andalucia under project SEJ4941. MP gratefully
acknowledges financial support from de Fonds de recherche sur la soci´et´e et la culture under
project 133431.
Also affiliated with Universit´e du Littoral Cˆote d’Opale (ULCO).
Also affiliated with CIREQ and IZA.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.
1074 On unions and severance pay
world. These arrangements differ substantially. In some countries, such as
Canada and Spain, severance pay is government-mandated. In others, such
as Japan and the United States, it is reached through private bargaining.
In yet other countries, it is partly government-mandated and partly reached
through bargaining (e.g., Belgium, France, Germany, and Italy). In countries
where arrangements for severance pay are reached privately, this can
occur through individual contractual arrangements, or through collective
bargaining with unions.1
The existing literature on severance pay has mainly considered
government-mandated severance pay.2However, severance pay reached
through collective or private agreements is quantitatively important. For
instance, using data from Massachusetts in the United States in which
86 percent of workers were covered by a severance pay agreement,
Kodrzycki (1998) shows that a typical arrangement features severance pay
of one week’s wage per year of service. Assuming a replacement rate of
unemployment insurance (UI) of 50 percent, this implies that total severance
pay receipts are higher than maximum potential UI receipts for workers
with more than 13 years of tenure. On average, severance pay amounts to
43 percent of maximum available UI receipts for displaced workers in the
sample of Kodrzycki (1998).
If privately reached severance pay agreements are important, this raises
the question of why publicly mandated regimes exist, and how the levels
of severance pay they impose compare with the ones that would come
out of private arrangements. Therefore, the main aim of this paper is a
theoretical and quantitative analysis of private bargaining over severance
pay. We conduct this analysis in a standard Diamond–Mortensen–Pissarides
(DMP) model with bargaining not only over wages, but also over severance
pay. This set-up then allows us to assess how counterfactual, simulated
estimates of privately bargained severance pay compare with observed,
government-mandated levels.
As already alluded to above, collective bargaining cannot be neglected
when analyzing the determination of severance pay. The evidence presented
in Parsons (2005a,b,c) shows very clearly that severance pay arrangements
differ substantially by unionization status of the employee. There is also
evidence that severance payments are indeed negotiated by unions (Millward
et al., 1992), and that, because of the complexity of employment protection
legislation, unions are able to obtain higher firing costs for their members
(Colonna, 2008a,b). Thus, an additional contribution of this paper is to
1See Holzmann et al. (2012), particularly Annex B, for a classification of countries by type of
severance pay arrangement, and see Laga (2012) for some country specific details.
2An important exception, which we discuss below, is Fella and Tyson (2013).
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.
S. Auray, S. Danthine, and M. Poschke 1075
analyze union behavior in this context. This turns out to be important for
understanding the arrangements in several countries.
Before delving into the theoretical analysis, we discuss evidence on
severance pay in Europe (Section II). In doing so, we do not limit
ourselves to popular measures, such as those from the World Bank and
the OECD, which only cover legally mandated severance pay. Instead, we
focus particularly on negotiated components of severance pay resulting
from bargaining. Of course, privately bargained severance pay might not be
observed in countries where legally mandated levels exceed those that would
result from private negotiation. For these cases, our model can provide
an indication of which counterfactual arrangements could prevail in the
absence of legal provisions.
To analyze bargaining over severance pay, we build a matching model in
the manner of Mortensen–Pissarides with endogenous job destruction and
risk-averse workers, and we add (i) unions as in Delacroix (2006), and (ii)
bargaining over wages and severance payments as in Booth (1994, 1995). A
first theoretical result shows that a worker and a firm bargaining over both
wages and severance pay opt for a level of severance pay that gives the
worker full insurance. This arises because the risk-neutral firm can insure
the risk-averse worker. The level of severance pay required for this decreases
with the UI replacement rate and the job-finding rate. Expressed relative to
average completed tenure, it also depends on the job-destruction rate.
A second theoretical result shows that a monopolistic union that chooses
wages and severance pay to maximize the value of employment, taking
firms’ reactions as given, also chooses full insurance. How much surplus
the union can extract is limited by the equilibrium reaction of job creation
to higher wages and severance pay.
In order to provide quantitative results, we calibrate the model to a set of
eight continental European economies that feature varying levels and types
of arrangements for severance pay. We then first use the calibrated model
to compare outcomes from bargaining to union behavior, taking severance
pay as given. We then perform a number of quantitative counterfactual
experiments on severance pay using the calibrated model. These can be
grouped into two sets of exercises, one aiming to understand the effect of
varying severance pay, and another aiming to provide an indication of what
levels of severance pay would be bargained privately. This second set can
serve as a benchmark to which legislated levels of severance pay can be
compared.
The first set of exercises indicates that exogenously eliminating
mandated severance pay increases job destruction but also increases job
creation, and thus has an ambiguous effect on unemployment. This is
in line with results from the literature, in particular Blanchard (2000)
and Ljungqvist (2002). In calibrated economies, we find that the change
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2019.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT