The Production Life Cycle

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12255
Published date01 October 2018
Date01 October 2018
AuthorYibei Liu,Ben G. Li
Scand. J. of Economics 120(4), 1139–1170, 2018
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12255
The Production Life Cycle*
Ben G. Li
Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467, USA
ben.li@bc.edu
Yibe i Liu
Yale-NUSCollege, Singapore 138610
yibei.liu@yale-nus.edu.sg
Abstract
Tasks in production have different dynamics from individuals products. We build a general
equilibrium model where three forces (i.e., offshoring, learning, and wage) interact to determine
how production fragmentation evolvesover time. We showthat the production process follows a
life cycle: its fragmentation emerges,deepens, and converges. Our model is stylized and versatile,
and it can be used to tractably characterize the loci of global output, productivity, welfare, and
value-added distribution as production fragmentation progresses.
Keywords: Industrialization; learning-by-doing; offshoring; product cycle
JEL classification:F63; O14
I. Introduction
When the current round of globalization began half a century ago, Vernon
(1966) hypothesized that industrial products have a life cycle: they originate
and are first produced in the industrialized North, and then are imitated
and produced in the less industrialized South. Vernon proved to be right, as
the following 50 years have witnessed the continual Southern takeover of
Northern products. However, Vernon’s product life cycle was not the only
ongoing cycle. During the same period, many Northern products retained
their Northern identities, although their production was progressively
fragmented and gradually moved to the South. This phenomenon, which
we refer to as the “production life cycle”, unraveled the era of global
manufacturing, including offshoring by the North, industrialization of the
Also affiliated with Deakin Business School, Victoria3125, Australia.
*Wethank Jim Anderson, Davin Chor, Paola Conconi,Thibault Fally, Gita Gopinath, Juan Carlos
Hallak, Wolfgang Keller, Hideo Konishi, Jim Markusen, Keith Maskus, Larry Qiu, John Ries,
HeiwaiTang,Jon Vogel,StephenYeaple,and Kei-MuYi, as well as the two anonymousreferees, for
their valuable comments during different stages of the paper.We also thank seminar/conference
participants at various places.Any remaining errors are our own.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.
1140 The production life cycle
South, global output increments, income redistribution, and the formation
of value chains.
A theoretical model of the production life cycle is needed, one that
should feature general equilibrium to consolidate input and output markets,
that should be dynamic to generate time-varying patterns, and that should
be tractable so that future studies can easily extend it. In this paper, we
endeavor to build such a model. In our model, production fragments (tasks)
of an industrial product have different levels of sophistication and the South
has weaker technologies than the North for sophisticated tasks. Cheaper
Southern labor incentivizes the North to offshore tasks for which Southern
technologies are either as efficient as, or moderately less efficient than, their
Northern counterparts. Offshored tasks of both types benefit the North by
lowering costs, while only those of the second type provide the South with
opportunities to improve its technologies. Through learning-by-doing, the
South has its wage rates elevated and its scope of tasks expanded.
Our model provides a uniform framework for rationalizing the
production life cycle: what it means, how it looks, why it happens, and
where it starts and ends. It predicts convergence as a unique characteristic
of the production life cycle, which does not occur in Vernon’s product
life cycle. There is a steady state at which tasks are allocated across
countries in proportion to their sizes. Before the steady state is reached,
income converges across countries through offshoring, even though there
exist perpetual technological gaps across countries. The South improves
its productivity, and thus its income, until the steady state is reached.
Intuitively, as all tasks are needed for making a product, within-product
comparative advantage causes specialization in tasks and learning-by-doing
eliminates technological gaps on offshored tasks. This is a new channel
through which global income converges rather than diverges.
Our model also provides five other findings. First, the output of global
production can be sufficiently characterized using a production function
with three elements: Northern labor, Southern labor, and a total task
productivity (TTP) term. Specifically, the productivity gains for the South
through learning-by-doing and those for the North through offshoring are
aggregable into a single TTP that increases and converges to its steady-state
level. This remarkably simplifies the analysis of global production, whose
major working forces can be showcased separately without recounting every
dynamic general equilibrium effect.
Second, we use the task type of average labor to measure a country’s
position along the global chain of tasks, and find that the North moves up
the chain by specializing in high-end tasks at which it excels. The South
also moves up, but as a net outcome of two effects: an up-effect due to
learning-by-doing, and a down-effect resulting from the sophisticated tasks
it conducts as a semi-qualifier. The two effects counteract each other and the
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.
B. G. Li andY. Liu 1141
up-effect dominates, owing to the Southern wage increments that exhaust
the Southern cost advantage and thus limit the scope of offshoring in every
period.
Third, along the course of convergence, the South is better off while
the North experiences a period of worsening welfare prior to the steady
state. This is because tasks that are more sophisticated do not generate
more employment and thus offshoring reduces the demand for Northern
labor. Our model also sheds light on the relationships between offshoring
and other global trends. As offshoring expands, Southern net imports rise,
Northward migration tends to decline, and technology payments can be paid
in either direction.
Fourth, the value added by the South to a given product increases at a
decreasing rate. As the South improves productivity and receives more tasks,
its wage rate rises and thus offshoring slows down. During this process, the
South still adds more value to the product but those value increments shrink
gradually.
Lastly, our model provides another mechanism that explains why having
a small country size is disadvantageous in economic development.1It is
difficult to identify, in retrospect, which Southern countries in the 1960s
were destined to prosper. If any similarity existed among those countries
that later became prosperous, it was a relatively large (rather than absolute)
population size.2In our model, if a Southern country is so small that its
initially assigned tasks match or exceed its share of the world labor force,
it would not have learning potential later.
Our paper is related to both the bodies of literature on international
trade and economic growth. The related body of literature on international
trade can be divided into two groups. The first group models industrial
cycles but does not have offshoring involved. Their industrial cycles are
product life cycles in Vernon’s style (Krugman, 1979; Dollar, 1986; Jensen
and Thursby, 1986, 1987; Segerstrom et al., 1990; Grossman and Helpman,
1991a,b).3These studies built on the new trade theory and thus relied
on product (variety) as the unit of analysis. The second group models
offshoring but does not generate industrial cycles (Kremer, 1993; Feenstra
1For discussions on the small-country disadvantage, see Alesina and Spolaore (1997), Easterly
and Rebelo (1993), and Commonwealth Consultative Group (1997).
2On the basis of our calculation, present emerging market economies accounted for 22 percent
of the world population (China and India excluded) in the year 1966. Their average population
(26.5 million) ranked as the 26th largest country in the world at that time. In comparison, present
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development countries accounted for 32 percent,
with their average population ranked 20th (32.7 million), at that time. Details are available on
request.
3For recent empirical studies on product cycles, see Feenstraand Rose (2000), Xiang (2014) and
Zhu (2005).
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT