Social Security Income and Health Care Spending: Evidence from the Social Security Notch

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12218
Date01 April 2018
Published date01 April 2018
AuthorYuping Tsai
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.
Scand. J. of Economics 120(2), 440–464, 2018
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12218
Social Security Income and Health Care
Spending: Evidence from the Social Security
Notch*
Yuping Tsai
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Atlanta, GA 30329, USA
ytsai@cdc.gov
Abstract
In this paper, I exploit Social Security legislation changes to identify the causal effect
of Social Security income on out-of-pocket medical expenditures of the elderly. Using
the 1986–1994 Consumer Expenditure Survey and an instrumental variables strategy,
the empirical results show that health care expenditures are responsive to changes in
Social Security income for elderly individuals with less than a high-school education.
The estimated income elasticities are between 1.41 and 3.47, depending on the outcome
measures, and are statistically significant at conventional levels. The findings are in
contrast to existing studies that find a small income elasticity at the individual/household
level.
Keywords: Health care expenditures; income elasticity; Social Security benefits
JEL classification:H55; I10; J14
I. Introduction
Understanding the relationship between income and health care spending
is important for several reasons. First, the findings have implications
for how health care spending is likely to evolve and the optimality of
the growth of the health care sector. If health care spending increases
considerably with income so that rising income can explain most or all of
the rising costs of health care, it would be more likely that the increasing
share of gross domestic product allocated to health is socially optimal
(Acemoglu et al., 2013). Second, it could affect how policy evaluations
are conducted because policies that affect individual/household income
might also affect how they consume medical care. The topic has naturally
received considerable attention from researchers (Kleiman 1974; Newhouse
and Phelps, 1976; Newhouse, 1977; Maxwell, 1981; Leu, 1986; Brown,
1987; Manning et al., 1987; Parkin et al., 1987; Gerdtham et al., 1992;
*The content of this paper does not reflect the official opinion of the Centers for Disease
Control and Prevention. Responsibility for the information and views expressed in the paper
lies entirely with the author.
Y. Tsai 441
Barros, 1998; Di Matteo and Di Matteo, 1998; Fogel, 1999; Gerdtham and
Jonsson, 2000; Freeman, 2003; Di Matteo, 2004; Moscone and Tosetti,
2010; Acemoglu et al., 2013). However, their findings are inconsistent
and generally vary by the level of health care spending – at the national
level, the income elasticity of health care expenditures is greater than 1
while the income elasticity at the individual/household level is typically
near zero (Getzen, 2000).
There are relatively few studies in this body of literature that use the
individual/household-level data, in part due to the virtue that income is
usually not a policy instrument to affect the demand for health care,
and also due to the limited availability of data for both the income
and health care expenditure variables. However, the primary reason is
the potential endogeneity of individual/household income. Most previous
studies compare health care expenditures by household income or by
poverty status. Thus, omitted-variable bias is a serious concern because
income is most likely to correlate with unobservables that associate with
health care spending. One example is that healthy individuals are likely to
have higher income while their health care spending is likely to be low.
Not controlling for the health status of the individual would lead to a
downward bias in estimating the income effect on health care expenditures.
To my knowledge, only one study, the Rand Health Insurance Experiments,
has addressed this issue (Newhouse and the Insurance Experiment Group,
1993). Between 1974 and 1981, the experiment randomly assigned families
to health insurance plans with different levels of cost-sharing. The sample
included families with adults under the age of 62. Although the focus
of the study is to assess the effect of cost-sharing on medical service
use and health, a subexperiment finds that a small, unanticipated, and
temporary increase in one’s income has no significant impact on one’s
health care expenditures.1,2
The goal of this study is to estimate the responsiveness of household
health care expenditures to changes in income, focusing exclusively on
the elderly population and on the Social Security portion of their income.
To my knowledge, this is the first study to estimate the income elasticity
1The subexperiment gave an annual lump-sum payment of a maximum of US$250 to a
subsample of families and the results show that the group with the extra payment had US$4.5
lowerexpenditures than the control group. However, the result cannot truly represent the income
elasticity of health care expenditures in general because the income increase is temporary
and unanticipated.
2Previous studies have estimated the income elasticity of medical service utilization. For
example, using data from the 1963 Center for Health Administration Studies survey, Newhouse
and Phelps (1974) find that elasticities with respect to wage income are around 0.15 to
0.35 for hospital days and 0.1 for physician visits. Newhouse and Phelps (1976) find a
small income elasticity of hospital and physician services (i.e., in the range of 0.03 to 0.14).
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT