Social Comparisons and Optimal Taxation in a Small Open Economy

Published date01 October 2019
Date01 October 2019
AuthorTomas Sjögren,Thomas Aronsson,Olof Johansson‐Stenman
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12308
Scand. J. of Economics 121(4), 1500–1532, 2019
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12308
Social Comparisons and Optimal Taxation
in a Small Open Economy*
Thomas Aronsson
Ume˚a University, SE-901 87 Ume˚a, Sweden
thomas.aronsson@umu.se
Olof Johansson-Stenman
University of Gothenburg, SE-405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden
olof.johansson@economics.gu.se
Tomas Sj¨ogren
Ume˚a University, SE-901 87 Ume˚a, Sweden
tomas.sjogren@umu.se
Abstract
In this paper, we analyzehow international capital mobility affects the optimal labor and capital
income tax policy in a smallopen economy when consumers care about relative consumption. The
main results crucially depend on whether the governmentcan tax returns on savings abroad. If the
government can use flexible residence-based capital income taxes, then the optimal policyr ules
from a closed economy largely carry overto the case of a small open economy.If it cannot, then
capital income taxes become completely ineffective.The labor income taxes must then indirectly
also reflect the corrective purpose that the absent capital income tax would have had.
Keywords: Capital mobility; optimal taxation; positional goods; relative consumption; small
open economy
JEL classification:D03; D60; D62; F21; H21; H23
I. Introduction
People care about their relative consumption (i.e., how much they consume
relative to what other people consume).1While this insight has a long
history, and was noted by the founding fathers of economics, including
*The authors are grateful for helpful comments from two anonymous referees and participants
at the Regional Science Association conference in Graz 2016. Research grants from the Bank of
Sweden Tercentenary Foundation, the Swedish Council for Working Life and Social Research,
and the Swedish Tax Agency (RS10-1319:1) are also gratefully acknowledged.
1For empirical evidence from research on happiness and from questionnaire-based experimental
research,s ee, forexample, Easterlin (1995, 2001), Johansson-Stenman et al. (2002), Blanchflower
and Oswald (2004), Ferrer-i-Carbonell (2005), Solnick and Hemenway (2005), Carlsson et al.
(2007), and Clark and Senik (2010).
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
T.Aronsson, O. Johansson-Stenman, and T. Sj ¨ogren 1501
Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill, the literature dealing with the optimal tax
policy implications of relative consumption comparisons is more recent. Our
paper contributes to this body of literature by considering an intertemporal
model of a small open economy with a mobile capital stock, where the
government redistributes and corrects for externalities by using nonlinear
labor income and capital income taxes. We show that the optimal tax policy
responses to relative concerns crucially depend on whether the government
can observe and tax the returns on savings abroad through a flexible
residence-based capital income tax. Under quite realistic assumptions, the
optimal tax policy response can differ considerably from the tax policies
prescribed by closed-economy models in earlier studies.
Most earlier studies dealing with the tax policy implications of social
comparisons are based on static models of closed economies, and they
do not address the potential role of capital income taxation. A major
finding in this literature is that relative consumption comparisons typically
imply much higher optimal marginal labor income tax rates than in
standard economic models (without any social comparisons), because
relative consumption concerns give rise to large negative externalities. The
literature also explains how this corrective tax element will be modified
when information asymmetries prevent redistribution through lump-sum
taxes.2To our knowledge, Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2010) were
the first to analyze the role of capital income taxation in an economy where
people care about relative consumption, and where the government can
simultaneously use an optimal nonlinear labor income tax for purposes
of redistribution and externality correction.3They found that consumer
preferences for relative consumption have important implications for capital
income taxation even when the labor income tax is optimal, because the
positional externalities that consumers impose on one another can vary
both over the individual life cycle and over time in general. The more
(less) positional people become over time, the stronger will typically be
the argument for taxing (subsidizing) savings at the margin.4
2The earlier literature in this area includes Boskin and Sheshinski (1978), Oswald (1983),
Tuomala (1990), Ljunqvist and Uhlig (2000), Dupor and Liu (2003), Aronsson and Johansson-
Stenman (2008), and Eckerstorfer and Wendner(2013).
3See also Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2014a) for a generalization, in particular with
respect to the nature of the social comparisons. See Abel (2005) for a study of first-best optimal
capital income taxation in a representative-agent economy(without any labor income tax), where
the representative consumer has preferences for relative consumption.
4For instance, if people become more positional when their income increases, as suggested by
empirical evidence in Clark et al. (2008), there is an incentive to tax capital income at the margin
in a growing economy where people become more positional overtime. Similarly, if the young
are more positional than the old, which is consistent with some empirical evidence (Pingle and
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
1502 Optimal taxation in a small open economy
However, the studies on optimal taxation refer red to above, and indeed
almost all previous studies in the policy-oriented literature on relative
consumption, are based on closed-model economies.5This is problematic
when dealing with capital taxation as most (if not all) developed countries
are open to capital mobility. Our main contribution in this paper is that
we generalize the setting of Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2010) to
a small open economy with capital mobility where individuals can invest
their savings either domestically or abroad. This generalization is clearly
important because capital mobility can seriously restrict the use of capital
income taxation as a means of correction and redistribution.
The point of departure is the optimal income tax model with overlapping
generations (OLG) developed by Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2010),
where (realistic) information asymmetries prevent the government from
using type-specific lump-sum taxes for purposes of redistribution. Here,
this model is augmented with an international capital market, and it is
embedded into the framework of a small open economy.6A small open
economy is here meant to imply that the country is small enough for its
government to treat the world market interest rate as exogenous – a realistic
assumption for many (if not most) countries. Nevertheless, at the end of
Section III, we comment on how the results would change if the economy
were large in the sense that the government is able to (strategically) affect
the world market interest rate.
The scope for capital income taxation will, of course, depend on
whether all capital income is observable to the government. Following the
terminology in the literature on capital income taxation in open economies,
we refer to “source-based” capital income taxation when the capital income
is taxed at the source (i.e., imposed by the country where this income is
generated, irrespective of whether the income earner is a domestic or foreign
resident). In contrast, “residence-based” capital income taxation means
that the tax is levied on the citizens of a particular country, irrespective of
whether they earn their income domestically or abroad. An individual who
Mitchell, 2002; Johansson-Stenman and Martinsson, 2006), it is, for this reason, desirable to
subsidize capital income at the margin.
5To our knowledge,the only exceptions are Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2014b), with an
examination of the optimal provision of public goods, and Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman
(2015), dealing with optimal income taxation in two-country economies with social comparisons
within as well as between countries.
6Many earlier studies have examined the implications of international capital mobility for
revenue collection and provisionof public goods at the national level in contexts without relative
consumption comparisons; see, for example, Zodrow and Mieszkowski (1986), Wilson (1986),
Bucovetsky and Wilson (1991), and Huber (1999). See also Aronsson and Sj ¨ogren (2014),
who analyze the tax policy implications of quasi-hyperbolic discounting in an economy with
international capital mobility.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT