Reference Pricing with Elastic Demand for Pharmaceuticals

Published date01 January 2018
Date01 January 2018
AuthorRicardo Gonçalves,Vasco Rodrigues
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12207
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.
Scand. J. of Economics 120(1), 159–182, 2018
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12207
Reference Pricing with Elastic Demand for
Pharmaceuticals*
Ricardo Gon¸calves
Universidade Cat´olica Portuguesa, 4169-005 Porto, Portugal
rgoncalves@porto.ucp.pt
Vasco Rodrigues
Universidade Cat´olica Portuguesa, 4169-005 Porto, Portugal
vrodrigues@porto.ucp.pt
Abstract
In this paper, we re-examine the properties of two commonly adopted government
reimbursement schemes for pharmaceuticals: reference pricing and fixed percentage
reimbursement. We depart from the previous literature by assuming that the individual
demand is price-sensitive and depends on the copayment rate (i.e., the part paid by each
consumer). We obtain two novel results under reference pricing: first, as the copayment
rate increases, so do pharmaceutical prices; second, this increase in pharmaceutical
prices reduces social welfare. Whilst reference pricing does emerge as a preferable
reimbursement scheme, demand elasticities and the copayment rate interact in complex
ways. This leads (unexpectedly) to the possibility that a higher copayment rate (lower
reimbursement rate) results in higher government expenditure.
Keywords: Copayment rates; pharmaceutical reimbursement schemes
JEL classification:I18; L13
I. Introduction
Purchasing pharmaceuticals is different from purchasing other goods:
demand is often relatively inelastic and, in a large number of countries,
individuals only pay a fraction of the price of the prescription
pharmaceuticals they consume, whilst the government (or other third-party
payers) are responsible for the remainder. Two widely adopted schemes to
determine their relative contributions are fixed percentage reimbursement
(FPR) and reference pricing (RP). Under FPR, the government pays a fixed
Both authors are affiliated with Cat´olica Porto Business School and CEGE.
*Financial support from Funda ¸ao Ciˆencia e Tecnologia (projects PTDC/EGE-
ECO/100296/2008 and PEst-OE/EGE/UI0731/2011) is gratefully acknowledged. We thank
elder Vasconcelos, Ricardo Ribeiro, Odd Rune Straume, two referees, and participants of
the 2012 European Conference in Health Economics (Zurich), 6th Portuguese Economic
Journal Meeting (2012, Porto), and 13th Portuguese Health Economics Conference (2013,
Braga) for helpful comments and suggestions.
160 Reference pricing with elastic demand for pharmaceuticals
percentage of the pharmaceutical’s price and the patient is responsible for
the remainder (also known as the copayment rate). By contrast, under RP,
within each cluster of pharmaceuticals,1one is chosen as the “reference”
and the government only pays a fixed fraction of the “reference”
pharmaceutical’s price, even if the consumer buys a more expensive
alternative.2
In the last decades, RP has become a widely used scheme for price
and (public) expenditure control in pharmaceutical markets. It has attracted
significant attention in the literature, and a large consensus has emerged
regarding its merits. Most models in the literature on RP share two
common features: first, they assume pharmaceuticals are differentiated;
second, they typically make the assumption of unit demand (i.e., each
consumer is assumed to purchase exactly one unit of a pharmaceutical
variety or none). Under the assumption of unit demand with full market
coverage (e.g., Brekke et al., 2007), it should not be surprising that social
welfare is equal across reimbursement regimes as there are no quantity
effects. Reimbursement regimes merely determine who captures the surplus
created, but not its amount.
In this paper, our main aim is to analyze the impact of considering
that each individual consumer’s demand depends on prices – a clear
departure from the previous literature, which commonly assumes individual
unit demand – under reimbursement schemes such as FPR and RP,
in a full market coverage setting with differentiated pharmaceuticals.
This strikes us as a realistic assumption, at least for some health
conditions. For instance, in the treatment of health conditions that
result in recurring episodes of symptoms of variable intensity, such as
sleeping disorders, muscular pain, and migraines, pharmaceuticals might
be prescribed during a significant period of time (e.g., under long-
term prescriptions). It is entirely plausible that the patient might react
to the price of the prescribed pharmaceutical when deciding whether
to take it on a specific occasion.3Even in the treatment of chronic
diseases and conditions, such as hypertension, high cholesterol, and
asthma, treatment adherence has been shown to depend on patients’
1Several criteria could be used to cluster pharmaceuticals: chemical, pharmacological, and
therapeutic (Miraldo, 2009).
2Naturally, RP is only viable if more than one pharmaceutical is available for the treatment
of a condition, and it is especially used when low-price generic competition exists. For more
detailed reviews of RP, see L´opez-Casasnovas and Puig-Junoy (2000) and Galizzi et al. (2011).
3It is important to note that the most obvious candidate to satisfy this assumption is the
over-the-counter (OTC) market for pharmaceuticals. However, OTC pharmaceuticals are not
subject to prescription and, hence, typically fall outside the scope of reimbursement schemes.
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2016.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT