Progressive Tax and Inequality in a Unionized Economy*

Date01 January 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12328
Published date01 January 2020
Scand. J. of Economics 122(1), 38–80, 2020
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12328
Progressive Tax and Inequality in a
Unionized Economy*
Chun-Chieh Huang
Fu Jen Catholic University, New Taipei City 24205, Taiwan
cchuang@mail.fju.edu.tw
Juin-Jen Chang
Academia Sinica, Taipei 11529, Taiwan
jjchang@econ.sinica.edu.tw
Hsiao-Wen Hung
Tamkang University, New Taipei City 25137, Taiwan
hwhung@mail.tku.edu.tw
Abstract
In this paper, we develop a heterogeneous-agent, endogenous growth model of a unionized
economywith distinct progressive tax schedules on labor and capital income. Withtime preference
heterogeneity,the effective labor force, balanced growth,and income inequality are endogenously
determined, and these interact with each other.A reduction in the degree of progressive labor tax
yields a “double-dividend”in terms of reducing income inequality and boosting economic g rowth,
while capital income progressivity displays the usual growth–inequality trade-off. Particularly,
the double-dividend effect becomes more pronounced when unionization is declined or trade
unions become more wage-oriented, leading to the so-called “Cheshire cat” phenomenon.
Keywords: Progressive taxation; trade-off between inequality and growth; unionization
JEL classification:D31; J52; O15; O40
I. Introduction
The potential trade-off between economic growth (efficiency) and income
distribution (equality) has been a central issue ever since modern economic
growth theory began. As for policy-makers, more aggressive redistribution,
typically through more progressive income taxation, can lead to lower
economic growth. The beneficial effect of a more progressive tax system
on income distribution is then traded off against the efficiency loss arising
from distorting labor supply and capital accumulation.
*Wethank Ping Wang, Been-Lon Chen, Ching-Chong Lai, Jang-Ting Guo, Hsieh-Yu Lin,Wei-
Neng Wang, the anonymous referee, and participants at the 13th Annual Conference of the
Association for Public EconomicTheor y andAEI-Five Joint Workshop2014 for their comments.
Weare also g rateful for financial support from the Ministry of Science and Technology,Taiwan.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
C-C. Huang, J-J. Chang, and H-W. Hung 39
Can progressive income taxation really promote income equality? The
decline in tax progressivity associated with the 1986 Tax Reform Act has
increased income inequality in the United States (Altig and Carlstrom,
1999; Li and Sarte, 2004). However, in a cross-country comparison, the
OECD (2012) finds that more progressive taxation does not necessarily
result in a more equal income distribution. For a large panel of countries,
Duncan and Sabirianova Peter (2016) also show that tax progressivity is not
effective at reducing income inequality: relative to the poor, the rich are able
to more effectively respond to a more progressive tax schedule by reducing
their working hours or concealing their hard-to-verify income (e.g., capital
income). To compare the effect of the tax share versus income share over
the past four decades, Hartman (2002) and Bastagli et al. (2012) conclude
that progressive taxation has failed to reduce the disparity of real incomes,
given that income inequality has increased in most advanced economies
and many developing economies over the past few decades.
Does more progressive income taxation entail a trade-off between
economic growth and income distribution? Despite a vast body of literature
on the link between growth and inequality, no general consensus has
emerged. The empirical evidence is rather inconclusive on this trade-off
in the presence of more progressive income taxation. Alesina and Rodrik
(1994), Persson and Tabellini (1994), and Perotti (1996) find evidence
of a negative relationship between inequality and growth, while Partridge
(1997), Forbes (2000), and Frank (2009) find a positive relationship.1By
identifying structural breaks in economic growth for 140 countries, Berg
et al. (2012) have calculated “growth spells”, and they have found that the
growth duration (sustained growth) is positively related to the degree of
equality in the income distribution. Indeed, as shown by the Kuznets cur ve
(Kuznets, 1955; Barro, 2000), the trade-off between income inequality and
economic growth is not clear-cut, and it depends on different development
stages. As is evident, the policy relevance of progressive taxation is still a
controversial issue that needs a further thorough investigation.
In this paper, we address these important issues by incorporating three
novel features in a heterogeneous-agent, endogenous growth model: (i)
separate progressive tax codes for labor and capital income; (ii) a unionized
labor market; and (iii) an endogeneous effective labor force, which accounts
for both the employment rate and labor hours per worker. In the model,
heterogeneity arises from two sources (i.e., time preferences and capital
endowments), reflecting the empirical finding whereby average patience
explains a considerable fraction of the variation in wealth accumulation
1See Røed and Strøm (2002) or Wellerand Rao (2008) for a comprehensive survey.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
40 Progressive tax and inequality in a unionized economy
and income (see Dohmen et al., 2016).2It is crucial to distinguish between
labor and capital income taxes, because both tax schedules exhibit different
trends and vary widely across countries.3More importantly, the two
distinct taxes, as we show later, have very different policy implications
for inequality.
It is also important to introduce trade unionism into the model. Over
the past few decades, two influential countries – the United States and
the United Kingdom – with the largest declines in unionization have also
experienced the biggest increases in income inequality. The decline in
union density in the United States can account for about 20 percent of
the rise in wage inequality during the 1980s (Card, 1996; Dinardo et al.,
1996; Freeman, 1996; Fortin and Lemieux, 1997). Likewise, the trend of
de-unionization has also increased pay inequality in the United Kingdom
(Machin, 1997; Card et al., 2004; Visser and Checchi, 2011), Canada (Card
et al., 2004), New Zealand (Wallerstein, 1999), and other OECD countries
(Kahn, 2000). Although union densities have fallen sizably, trade unionism
still plays a crucial role in the determination of wages, as collective
bargaining coverage is still high.4More importantly, trade unionism is
interconnected with progressive taxation. In a unionized economy, the
impact of more progressive taxation crucially depends on the distribution
of the labor supply for different income groups, and on the employment
rates they face. The importance of the inequality in hours worked has been
stressed by the OECD (2012) and Krueger et al. (2010). The employment
rate is equally important, as inequality in labor earnings goes hand-in-hand
with low employment rates in several European Union countries, including
Belgium, Finland, France, and Italy (see Dreger et al., 2015). In the model,
both the employment rate and labor hours are endogenously determined.
Any tax progressivity change will affect the bargained employment rate
and wage rates, which in turn will influence the individual labor supply
decision at the hours-of-work margin. The intensive or extensive margin of
the effective labor force will alter growth and inequality. In the benchmark
model, we characterize a physical capital-driven balanced-growth-path
2The heterogeneities in time preferences and wealth endowment are important factors in
explaining the observed income inequality in the United States (Krusell and Smith, 1998;
Hendricks, 2004) and other industrialized countries (see Garc´ıa-Pe˜nalosa and Turnovsky, 2007).
3In OECD countries, the progressivity of labor taxes increases because of a cut in social security
contributions and an introduction of in-work tax benefits, targeted at lowerincomes, but capital
taxes become less progressive because of a decline in top marginal individual income tax rates.
Nevertheless, the degree of progressivity of the labor income tax is commonly higher than that
of the capital income tax.
4For example, the union density in France and Spain is roughly 10 percent, yet the collective
bargaining coverage in these countries is 92 and 68 percent, respectively.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT