Long‐Term Impact of Minimum Wages on Workers’ Careers: Evidence from Two Decades of Longitudinal Linked Employer–Employee Data

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12327
Published date01 October 2019
Date01 October 2019
AuthorAna Rute Cardoso
Scand. J. of Economics 121(4), 1337–1380, 2019
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12327
Long-Term Impact of Minimum Wages on
Workers’ Careers: Evidence from Two
Decades of Longitudinal Linked
Employer–Employee Data*
Ana Rute Cardoso
Institute for Economic Analysis (CSIC), 08193 Bellater ra, Barcelona, Spain
anarute.cardoso@iae.csic.es
Abstract
Weanalyze the impact of high youth minimum wages, relyingon two decades of linked employer–
employee data and a major law change. Alternative treatment/control groups follow from two
strands of the literature, one tracking low-skilled workers employed before the law change, who
are eligible for a large wage increase, and one tracking the employmentof full cohor ts, whether
working or in school when the lawchanged. High minimum wages led to a short-term wage gain,
which faded over time. They did not jeopardize employment prospects. Changes in the hours
worked by part-time workers point to increased job attachment.
Keywords: Employment; hours of work; teenage labor markets; wage growth
JEL classification:J08; J31; J24
I. Introduction
There is limited evidence on the impact of exposure to high youth
minimum wages on long-term labor market fortunes. Yet, economic theory
identifies several outcomes that are likely to be influenced by an increase
in the mandatory minimum wage. In particular, employers might reduce
the quantity of labor demanded and undercut the provision of training.
Likewise, individuals might change their labor supply if the minimum
wage influences job attachment or schooling decisions. These changes
would affect the accumulation of human capital and thus labor market
performance over the life cycle. However, depending on the theoretical
setting, we are confronted with contradictory predictions on the operation
*I am grateful to Manuel Arellano, David Card, Jo˜ao Cerejeira, David Dorn, Javier
Fern ´andez Blanco, Dan Hamermesh, David Jaeger, Patrick Kline, Ferran Ma˜e, Pedro Portugal,
Jos´e Varej˜ao, and the par ticipants of severalseminars and conferences for helpful comments, as
well as the Statistics Department of the Portuguese Ministry of Employment for data access. I
acknowledge the support of the Spanish Ministry of the Economy (SeveroOchoa Programme for
Centresof Excellence in R&D, SEV20150563), the AEI-Spain, and FEDER-UE (grant ECO2016-
76734-P).
Also affiliated with Barcelona GSE.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
1338 Long-term impact of minimum wages
of these mechanisms, and the scarcity of empirical evidence limits our
understanding of the process.
This paper analyzes the long-term impact of exposure to high youth
minimum wages on workers’ careers, focusing on the wage profile and
employment – at both intensive and extensive margins – over the life cycle.
Two sets of remarkable conditions are combined for the analysis of
this topic. First, a longitudinal matched employer–employee dataset of
unusual quality is available, which tracks the worker’s employment and
wage history from a young age and over two decades. Specifically, it covers
the population of workers and firms in the private sector in Portugal. The
few existing studies that deal with the long-term impact of the minimum
wage (Neumark and Nizalova, 2007; Dube etal., 2010; Dolton et al., 2012)
could not rely on individual longitudinal data.
Secondly, a sharp change in the legislation took place in the mid-1980s,
leading to a very large wage increase for a very specific group of workers.
On 1 January 1987, the minimum wage for workers aged 17 increased
by 50 percent, and for those aged 18 and 19 it increased by 33 percent.
These legislative changes were exploited by Pereira (2003), who investigated
the impact of minimum wages on firm-level employment, and by Portugal
and Cardoso (2006), who analyzed worker flows and firms’ recruitment
and dismissal policies. Both studies concentrated on firm-level employment
(stocks or flows) and were restricted to the short term, at most two years
after the change in legislation.
We follow up on those studies, extending their analyses into the long
term and for a wider set of outcomes. The core identification strategy
follows from Portugal and Cardoso (2006). Workers aged 16–18 in 1986
were eligible in January 1987 for a major increase in the applicable
minimum wage and were thus defined as the treatment group. Given that
those cohorts were eligible for the high minimum wage at different ages,
for different durations, and to different extents, we will also quantify the
impact of the minimum wage separately on each treated cohort. The control
group consists of workers aged 19 in 1986, who were never exposed to
the high youth minimum wage. In line with Portugal and Cardoso (2006),
we start out by defining the control and treatment groups conditional
on being employed in 1986, a strategy that has both advantages and
limitations. The advantage of this identification strategy is, first of all, that
the members of the treatment group were actually exposed to the high
minimum wage early in their working life. Secondly, it guarantees that
both the treatment and control groups were observed in the labor market,
having already left school, before any change in the law. Hence schooling
is not endogenous. However, this strategy raises concerns about sample
selection bias, as individuals working at young ages (16, 17, or 18) might
differ from those working at the age of 19, potentially leading to different
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
A. R. Cardoso 1339
wage and employment patterns over the life cycle. In particular, those who
drop out of school at the age of 16 are most likely to differ from those
who join the labor market later. Therefore, we also perform the analysis by
defining control and treatment groups irrespective of employment status
before the change in legislation. We compare individuals aged 19 and
employed in 1986 (control group) to those aged 19 and employed in 1987,
1988, and 1989 (the treatment groups, potentially exposed to the high
minimum wage for different durations). These two empirical strategies are
in line with different tracks of the previous literature. Whereas the bulk
of the analysis has been aimed at detecting the short-term impact of the
minimum wage on aggregate employment, studies with access to individual
longitudinal data have been aimed at detecting its impact on the probability
of remaining employed for low-skilled individuals already holding a job,
whose wages would have to increase to comply with the new minimum
(Currie and Fallick, 1996; Zavodny, 2000; Stewart, 2004a,b; Stewart
and Swaffield, 2008). Both approaches, whether concentrating on overall
employment for workers potentially affected or on subsequent employment
for low-wage workers who hold a job and are actually affected by the
minimum wage increase, are interesting in themselves. We will explore
both research avenues as we define alternative sets of treatment and control
groups.
We further check whether the schooling achievement of the cohorts
aged 16–19 in 1986 could have been influenced by the change in the law.
This analysis, although constrained by data limitations, suggests that the
sharp rise in youth minimum wages was a contributing factor in the rise
in university completion rates that took place in the country at that time.
This finding reinforces the interest in comparing the treatment and control
groups already observed in the labor market before the change in the law,
whose decisions to leave school had thus not been influenced by the youth
minimum wage level.
Section II describes the mechanisms that can cause youth minimum
wages to have a long-term impact on workers’ careers. Section III explores
the institutional and economic setting in Portugal. In particular, it provides
evidence on changes in the teenage wage distribution after the minimum
wage increase, showing the high degree of compliance with the new
legislation. Section IV describes the data and provides details on the
treatment and control groups. Section V addresses the question of whether
high youth minimum wages jeopardize future wage growth. It devotes
special attention to tackling the problem of separate identification of cohort,
age, and year effects in a wage regression. Section VI addresses the
question of whether high youth minimum wages undermine long-term
employment prospects. It first concentrates on the probability of working
part-time, conditional on working. It then models the number of hours
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT