Inertia Risk: Improving Economic Models of Catastrophes*

Published date01 October 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12381
Date01 October 2020
Scand. J. of Economics 122(4), 1259–1285, 2020
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12381
Inertia Risk: Improving Economic Models of
Catastrophes*
Anne-Sophie Cr´epin
The Beijer Institute of Ecological Economics, SE-104 05 Stockholm, Sweden
asc@beijer.kva.se
Eric Nævdal
The Frisch Centre, NO-0349 Oslo, Norway
eric.navdal@frisch.uio.no
Abstract
We model endogenous catastrophic risk in a newway. We call it “inertia risk”, whichaccounts
for delays between physical variables and the hazard rate – a characteristic often observed in
reality. The added realism significantly affects optimal policies relative to the standard model
of catastrophic risk. The probability of a catastrophe occurring at some point in time can span
the entire interval [0,1], and is not 0 or 1 as is typical in standard models. Inertia risk can also
generate path dependences. Weillustrate the implications for policy in a simple model of climate
change.
Keywords: Catastrophic risk; climate change; lagged effects; resource management
JEL classification:C02; C61; Q20; Q54
I. Introduction
Recent years have seen growing awareness that human activity increases the
risk of regime shifts (substantial, persistent, and abrupt system changes;
Biggs et al., 2012a), some with potentially catastrophic effects (Steffen
et al., 2004, 2015; Rockstr¨om et al., 2009).1Given the tight social
and ecological interactions in many managed systems, economic models
focusing on regime shifts should incorporate processes likely to trigger
such shifts (Levin et al., 2012; Cr´epin and Folke, 2015). Economic analysis
of regime shifts leads to dynamic resource management problems where
stochastic processes can trigger rapid and dramatic changes. In continuous
*For funding, wethank the Ebba and Sven Schwartz Foundation, the European Commission FP7
projectArctic Climate Change Economy and Society (Dnr 265863), and the Norwegian Research
Council, Norklima project (no.196199). A.-S. Cr´epin is affiliated with the Stockholm Resilience
Centre at Stockholm University (Sweden). We are grateful to William Brock, Atle Seierstad,
William Sigurdsson, and four anonymous reviewersfor valuable comments.
1The effects might also be beneficial. In order to simplify the discussion, weonly discuss negative
effects.
C
2019The Authors. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics published by John Wiley& Sons Ltd on behalf of F ¨oreningen
or utgivande av the SJE/The editors ofThe Scandinavian Journal of Economics.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative CommonsAttribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs License, which
permits use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properlycited, the use is non-commercial and no
modifications or adaptations are made.
1260 Inertia risk
time models, economists usually model catastrophic risk by assuming the
existence of a hazard rate that can depend on endogenous variables such
as CO2concentrations in the atmosphere or the size of fish stocks (Heal,
1984; Clarke and Reed, 1994; Tsur and Zemel, 1998; Gjerde et al., 1999).
The literature on the topic is largely theoretical, but with some empirical
applications (Cai et al., 2013; Lemoine and Traeger, 2014; Lontzek et al.,
2015).
The two most common approaches to modelling catastrophic risk in a
dynamic setting consider time-distributed catastrophes (TDCs, by far the
most common; e.g., Reed and Heras, 1992; Polasky et al., 2011) or state-
space-distributed catastrophes (SDCs; e.g., Tsur and Zemel, 1995; Nævdal,
2006).2These risk structures imply that either the catastrophe occurs with
probability 1 (TDCs) or the hazard rate is instantly responsive to changes
in control variables (SDCs). These properties are inadequate for many real-
world situations. We present an alternative risk structure that we call “inertia
risk”, which is a hybrid of both standard approaches. Inertia risk represents
real-life problems in a more realistic way, especially because it accounts
for dynamic lags between physical variables and the hazard rate, and it
allows for the possibility that substantial use of a resource at a certain level
might eventually be deemed safe.3This approach is particularly appropriate
for modelling renewable resource stocks such as fisheries (Polasky et al.,
2011), lakes (Scheffer and Carpenter, 2003), coral reefs (Hughes, 1994;
Norstr¨om et al., 2009), grasslands/savannah (Hirota et al., 2011), and global
phenomena such as planetary boundaries (Rockstr¨om et al., 2009; Steffen
et al., 2015). Some planetary boundaries relate to global-scale thresholds
linked to climate change, ocean acidification, and stratospheric ozone
depletion, while others – such as biogeochemical flows, land-system change,
and biodiversity loss – relate to regional thresholds (Rockstr¨om et al., 2009).
We study the implications of using our new risk structure, compared
with conventional models, in management models, using examples from
planetary boundaries and fisheries. However, we argue that the inertia risk
approach is applicable to other economic areas such as knowledge spillover
in relation to investments in R&D activities. The literature considers
different types of risk structures (Kamien and Schwartz, 1972; Doraszelski,
2003), but not inertia risk.
We show that inertia risk gives rise to optimal paths that differ from
the standard TDC approach in the following important respects.
2We introduce this terminology and are not aware of any alternative terminology for TDCs and
SDCs.
3We use the term “inertia” synonymously with “sluggishness”, and not in the technical sense
used in physics.
C
2019The Authors. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics published by John Wiley& Sons Ltd on behalf of F ¨oreningen
or utgivande av the SJE/The editors ofThe Scandinavian Journal of Economics.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT