Income Taxation and the Diversity of Consumer Goods: A Political Economy Approach*

Date01 July 2019
AuthorMichael T. Dorsch,Paul Maarek,Renaud Bourlès
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12307
Published date01 July 2019
Scand. J. of Economics 121(3), 960–993, 2019
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12307
Income Taxation and the Diversity of
Consumer Goods: A Political Economy
Approach*
Renaud Bourl`es
Aix-Marseille University,FR-13001 Marseille, France
renaud.bourles@centrale-marseille.fr
Michael T. Dorsch
School of Public Policy at Central European University, H-1051 Budapest, Hungary
dorschm@ceu.edu
Paul Maarek
Universit´ePanth´eonAssas, FR-75006 Paris, France
paul.maarek@u-paris2.fr
Abstract
After-tax income inequality has risen since the mid-1990s, as increases in market income
inequality have not been offset by greater fiscal redistribution. We argue that the substantial
increase in the diversity of consumer goods has mitigated mounting political pressures for
redistribution. Within a probabilistic voting framework, we demonstrate that if the share of
diversified goods in the consumption bundle increases sufficientlywith income, then an increase
in goods diversity can reduce the political equilibrium tax rate. Focusingon OECD countries, we
find empirical support for both the model’smicro-political foundations and the implied relation
between goods diversity and fiscal policy outcomes.
Keywords: Diversityof goods; probabilistic voting; redistribution; taxation
JEL classification:D72; D78; H24
I. Introduction
In the last decades, many countries have experienced a strong increase in
market income inequality that fiscal redistribution did not offset, leading to
*We are grateful for the thoughtful comments of participants at the annual meetings of the
European Public Choice Society (Groningen), at the ASSET conference (Grenada), and at the
LAGVconference (Marseille). In par ticular,we received comments that improved the paper from
Tok ´e Aidt, Nicolas Berman, Pierre Boyer,and C ´ecilia Garcia-Penalosa.Two anonymous referees
provided constructive criticisms that greatly improvedthe paper. Of course, all remaining errors
are our own. Some of this research was carried out while M. Dorsch and P. Maarek were visiting
the Aix-Marseille School of Economics and they are grateful for their hospitality and financial
support.
CNRS, EHESS, Centrale Marseille, Aix-Marseille School of Economics (AMSE).
LEMMA.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
R. Bourl`es, M. T. Dorsch, and P. Maarek 961
a significant increase in net income inequality; see Figure 1 (Piketty, 2014).
This led the International Monetary Fund to state in its last report (Gupta
and Keen, 2014) that reductions in the generosity of welfare benefits and
less progressive taxation have decreased the redistributive impact of fiscal
policy; see Figure 1.1We seek to add a new perspective to this now classic
puzzle in political economy: why democracies do not redistribute more and
what are the political economic limits to redistribution. More specifically,
we investigate why democracies have not offset the strong increase in
income inequality over the last decades.
We relate this limit to redistribution to the considerable increase in the
variety of consumer goods available in developed economies; see Figure 1
and Broda and Weinstein (2004, 2006), Hummels and Klenow (2005),
and Arkolakis et al. (2008) for empirical evidence.2This increase seems
mostly due to the increases in trade3and in R&D spending, including the
effects of R&D spillovers from abroad (Coe et al., 2009).4The key idea
of our paper is that this increase in goods diversity might have moderated
the tendency for a society to compensate the increases in inequality by
redistributing more. Figure 1 shows that average income tax rates on
average incomes have decreased and that fiscal freedom (as measured by
the Heritage Foundation) has increased.5Central to our argument is the
intuition that the welfare impacts of greater goods diversity might have been
heterogeneous across individuals, depending on the share of differentiated
goods in individuals’ consumption bundles. In this paper, we analyze how
such heterogeneous welfare effects of growth in the diversity of goods might
have affected individual preferences for fiscal redistribution, given that
private consumption becomes more valuable as goods diversity increases.
We also show how such a change in policy preferences might have affected
the equilibrium income tax rate within a political economic model.
More specifically, we build a model of probabilistic voting in which
voters spend their net income (after taxes and transfers) in private markets
1Gupta and Keen (2014) show that between the mid-1980s and mid-1990s, fiscal policy offset
about two-thirds of the 3.1 percentage point increase in market income inequality. Over the
subsequent decade (mid-1990s to mid-2000s), fiscal policy only offset about one-fifth of the 2.2
percentage point increase in the market income inequality.
2Bils and Klenow (2001) estimate that growthin the number of varieties of goods has accelerated
since 1980, and Broda and Weinstein(2006) estimate that the number of varieties (at the ten-digit
level) availableto consumers from trade flows has risen from 71,420 in 1971 to 259,215 in 2001.
More importantly, the number of goods categories (within which there are several varieties of
one good) has increased from 7,731 in 1972 to 16,390 in 2001.
3For example, an increase in diversity is an essential feature of trade models with monopolistic
competition (Krugman, 1979).
4In the theoretical part of our paper, we consider this increase in goods diversity as exogenous.
5For details concerning these variables, werefer readers to the empirical section of the paper.
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.
962 Income taxation and the diversity of consumer goods
Fig. 1. Empirical evidence from OECD countries
Notes: This figure shows the evolution over the last decades of income inequality, the variety of goods, and fiscal
outcomes. Note that the Gini coefficient is increasing with the degree of inequality,and that the Heritage Foundation
index is increasing the degree of fiscal freedom. All variablesare expressed as the yearly average over the OECD.
for two types of goods: one homogeneous and one that is a composition
of varieties. The diversity of goods then corresponds to the number of
varieties in the composite good. The key mechanism of our model comes
from a different allocation of income between those two types of goods
for different income levels. The intuition for this mechanism goes back to
Engel’s Law (Engel, 1857), which states that the share of food in household
spending decreases with income, and which we suppose extends to other
basic goods (clothing, shelter, transport, energy, health and sanitation, etc).
The share of normal goods and services (i.e., those that are not necessities)
in the consumption bundle should increase with income as a result (for
empirical evidence, see Bils and Klenow, 2001; Henry, 2014, 2015).
We assert that basic goods are produced mainly in competitive domestic
markets that did not benefit from the massive productivity gains of the past
decades, or from the accompanying increases in trade volumes (for instance,
international prices for many food commodities have increased over the last
decades). In this case, the introduction of new goods and services and the
subsequent increase in diversity should mainly affect the quantity of normal
differentiated goods available for consumers, which are often produced in
C
The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT