Experienced versus decision utility: large‐scale comparison for income–leisure preferences*

Published date01 October 2023
AuthorAlpaslan Akay,Olivier B. Bargain,H. Xavier Jara
Date01 October 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12538
Scand. J. of Economics 125(4), 823–859, 2023
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12538
Experienced versus decision
utility: large-scale comparison
for income–leisure preferences*
Alpaslan Akay
University of Gothenburg, SE-40530 Gothenburg, Sweden
alpaslan.akay@gu.se
Olivier B. Bargain
Bordeaux School of Economics, FR-33608 Pessac, France
olivier.bargain@u-bordeaux.fr
H. Xavier Jara
London School of Economics and Political Science, London, WC2A 2AE, UK
h.x.jara-tamayo@lse.ac.uk
Abstract
Subjective well-being (SWB) data are increasingly used to perform welfare analysis. Interpreted
as “experienced utility”, it has recently been compared to “decision utility” using small-scale
experiments most often based on stated preferences. We transpose this comparison to the
framework of non-experimental and large-scale data commonly used for policy analysis,
focusing on the income–leisure domain where redistributive policies operate. Using the British
Household Panel Survey, we suggest a “deviation” measure, which is simply the difference
between actual working hours and SWB-maximizing hours. We show that about three-quarters
of individuals make decisions that are not inconsistent with maximizing their SWB. We discuss
the potential channels that explain the lack of optimization when deviations are signif‌icantly
large. We f‌ind proxies for a number of individual and external constraints, and show that
constraints alone can explain more than half of the deviations. In our context, deviations partly
ref‌lect the inability of the revealed preference approach to account for labor market rigidities,
so the actual and SWB-maximizing hours should be used in a complementary manner. The
suggested approach based on our deviation metric could help identify labor market frictions.
Keywords: Decision utility; experienced utility; labor supply; subjective well-being
JEL classif‌ication:C90; I31; J22
*A. Akay acknowledges visiting f‌inancial support from the COV-POP project, funded by
the Nouvelle Aquitaine region, which has allowed completing the revision of this paper. We
acknowledge f‌inancial support from the Chaire BEWELL and the GPR HOPE, funded by the
“Investments for the Future” program (PIA) IdEx Universit´
e de Bordeaux. We are grateful to
discussants and participants at the ASSA meeting, the RES Conference, and various seminars
(ISER, DIAL, LISER, AMSE, IZA, BSE) for useful suggestions. Any errors remain our own.
Also aff‌iliated with Universidad Antonio de Nebrija, Madrid, Spain.
Also aff‌iliated with IZA.
c
2023 The Authors. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of F¨
oreningen
f¨
or utgivande av the SJE.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution
and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
824 Experienced versus decision utility: income–leisure preferences
1. Introduction
In economics, the standard approach to measure well-being relies on the
observation of decisions made by supposedly rational (utility-maximizing)
agents. The object derived from the “revealed preference” approach is
sometimes referred to as a “decision utility”. For more than two decades,
some authors have claimed that this decision utility is not always consistent
with the well-being associated with different experiences. They recommend
developing measures that focus more directly on “experienced utility”
(e.g., Dolan and Kahneman, 2008), such as self-reported information
on happiness, life satisfaction, or mental health. A growing amount of
evidence has shown that such subjective well-being (SWB) information
is not pure statistical noise: it ref‌lects some individual heterogeneity that
is closely associated with objective measures of well-being and, to some
extent, with behavior.1Yet, SWB is still seen by many as one argument,
among others, in the grand utility function of an individual (Rayo and
Becker, 2007; Benjamin et al., 2012; Glaeser et al., 2016).2Other studies
postulate that SWB answers, commonly provided in survey questionnaires,
are consistent with people’s revealed preferences (Oswald and Wu, 2010;
Decancq et al., 2015).
Whether there is congruence between individual decisions and the SWB
derived from these choices is still an open question. This is especially
disputable for key economic decisions (such as labor supply), which
imply a trade-off between several important dimensions of a good life
(e.g., consumption versus leisure). On the one hand, observed choices may
ref‌lect heuristics, optimization errors, or the fact that people have imperfect
information about what is good for them. Choices are also potentially limited
by many personal constraints (e.g., family obligations) and external factors
(e.g., market imperfections), the importance of which is diff‌icult to assess in
welfare analyses. On the other hand, SWB may not encompass the totality
of what humans are trying to achieve when they make decisions. Individual
choices may ref‌lect other life goals (e.g., fame) or values (e.g., helping others)
that partly differ from, or sometimes conf‌lict with, the pursuit of well-being
as we measure it in subjective data. Despite these sources of discrepancy, it
seems crucial to test whether there is (at least) minimal consistency between
decision utility and experienced utility.
1See Krueger and Schkade (2008) and Oswald and Wu (2010), as well as critical reviews
in Senik (2005), Clark et al. (2008), Kahneman and Krueger (2006), and Fleurbaey and
Blanchet (2013).
2K¨
oszegi and Rabin (2008) argue that both subjective and choice-based measures of well-being
contain unique information on a person’s true welfare, so that the ideal measure should perhaps
combine both types of data.
c
2023 The Authors. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of F¨
oreningen
f¨
or utgivande av the SJE.
A. Akay, O. B. Bargain, and H. X. Jara 825
This paper proposes a tangible approach to address this question
in the context of labor supply decisions. Rather than confronting the
ordinal preferences consistent with a decision-based versus experience-based
welfare metric,3we directly compare actual working hours (consistent
with decision-utility maximization) and optimal working hours (from the
perspective of experienced utility; i.e., hours that maximize income–leisure
satisfaction). The comparison is done on a large scale using nationally
representative data, from the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS). We
necessarily focus on single people, because the joint decision in couples is
diff‌icult to apprehend for individual welfare comparisons. Our single-value
“deviation” metric is a practical and convenient representation of the potential
discrepancies between decision and experienced utilities, which can be used
for inference and for exploring the determinants of these discrepancies – here
in the context of labor supply or, more generally, in analyses that traditionally
rely on the revealed preferences approach.
The suggested procedure goes as follows. We start by calculating the
distribution of deviations in the sample. To this end, we combine income and
leisure satisfaction domains to construct a proxy of experienced utility in the
income–leisure domain. We use this SWB measure to estimate an experienced
utility function, adopting a f‌lexible approach borrowed from the labor supply
literature. Using the estimated parameters and discretized income–leisure
bundles, we numerically search for the amount of working hours that would
maximize experienced utility and compare them with actual choices. We
f‌ind a broad overlap between actual work hours and SWB-maximizing work
duration. The average deviation is close to zero (2.9 hours). The negative sign
implies that people “overwork” on average according to SWB maximization,
but the deviation is not signif‌icantly different from zero for 72 percent of the
individuals in the sample. In other words, for a majority of people, actual
decisions are not inconsistent with the maximization of their income–leisure
satisfaction. We then attempt to describe the large discrepancies observed for
specif‌ic population subgroups (e.g., by gender, family composition, region
of residence, etc.), either characterized as “overworking” (a negative mean
deviation) or “underworking” (a positive mean deviation) from an SWB
perspective. Results suggest intuitive patterns regarding the direction of
the deviations. For instance, those living in London signif‌icantly overwork
(suggesting social norms or labor market constraints) while those with children
tend to work too little (suggesting childcare constraints or labor contracts that
are not f‌lexible enough). A detailed analysis by levels of worked hours
suggests that signif‌icant deviations are primarily due to those at the two ends
3This alternative approach is used in Akay et al. (2020) where money metrics are derived from
ordinal preferences consistent with either decisions or subjective experience.
c
2023 The Authors. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd on behalf of F¨
oreningen
f¨
or utgivande av the SJE.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT