Does the Welfare State Destroy the Family? Evidence from OECD Member Countries

Date01 April 2016
AuthorMario Lackner,Martin Halla,Johann Scharler
Published date01 April 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12144
Scand. J. of Economics 118(2), 292–323, 2016
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12144
Does the Welfare State Destroy the Family?
Evidence from OECD Member Countries
Martin Halla
University of Innsbruck, A-6020 Innsbruck, Austria
martin.halla@uibk.ac.at
Mario Lackner
University of Linz, A-4040 Linz, Austria
mario.lackner@jku.at
Johann Scharler
University of Innsbruck, A-6020 Innsbruck, Austria
johann.scharler@uibk.ac.at
Abstract
We study the effect of the size of the welfare state on demographic trends in OECD member
countries. Exploiting exogenous variation in public social spending, due to varying degrees
of political fractionalization (i.e., the number of relevant parties involved in the legislative
process), we show that an expansion in the welfare state increases fertility, marriage, and
divorce rates with a quantitatively stronger effect on the marriage rate. We conclude that the
welfare state supports family formation in the aggregate. Further, we find that the welfare
state decouples marriage and fertility, and therefore alters the organization of the average
family.
Keywords: Divorce; fertility; marriage; risk sharing; welfare state
JEL classification:D1; D62; H31; H53; J12; J13; J18
I. Introduction
Family and kinship traditionally provided services such as care for the
young and the elderly, and provided insurance against unforeseen events
such as illness and unemployment. Nowadays, governments in industrial-
ized countries provide, or at least subsidize, these services, for instance,
through public health and unemployment insurance. Thus, the role of the
family might have become less important in this respect (Anderberg, 2007),
and the incentives to form a family might have decreased along with the
For helpful comments, we would like to thank (among others) two anonymous referees.
The usual disclaimer applies. This research was funded by the Austrian Science Fund (FWF)
National Research Network S103, the Austrian Center for Labor Economics, and the Analysis
of the Welfare State.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
M. Halla, M. Lackner, and J. Scharler 293
introduction of comprehensive welfare state arrangements. Nevertheless, the
implementation of welfare state arrangements can incorporate (implicit or
explicit) subsidies of certain family arrangements. If, for instance, welfare
state regulations promote marriage and fertility, then the welfare state can
also exert a crowding-in effect on families. Consequently, the overall effect
is less clear.
Does the welfare state destroy or support the family? We study this
issue by examining OECD member countries in the period from 1980 until
2007. Thus, in contrast to the existing body of literature, which examines
specific welfare arrangements and reforms, we study the impact of welfare
state arrangements on an aggregated level. To measure the extent of the
welfare state, we mainly use public social spending as a percentage of the
gross domestic product (GDP), but we also use more specific measurements
such as public social spending on the family. Thus, we evaluate the effect
of the average implementation of the welfare state in the sample of OECD
member countries in the given time period. Demographic trends of family
outcomes are captured by marriage, divorce, and fertility rates.
To obtain exogenous variation in the size of the welfare state, we turn to
the literature on the political economy of public spending. This body of lit-
erature stresses the importance of political fractionalization for the level of
public spending.1We exploit varying degrees of political fractionalization
– in particular, the number of relevant parties involved in the legislative
process – as an instrumental variable. Our first-stage estimations show a
highly significant effect of within-country variation in political fraction-
alization on public (social) spending. The identifying assumption of our
instrumental variable strategy is that political fractionalization in the par-
liament affects family behavior only through the channel of public social
spending. While this assumption is not testable, there are few determinants
of family behavior that are reasonably correlated with political fractional-
ization. We discuss a number of potential mediating links (such as govern-
ment’s ideology or polarization, immigration, and taxation of families) and
show that our estimated effects are very robust to the inclusion of these
potential confounders. We hope that this discussion convinces the criti-
cal reader that using political fractionalization as an instrument for public
social spending is a useful identification strategy in our context.
1As we discuss in detail, the link between fractionalization and public spending can be
derived from different political economy theories of public finance. While the so-called
common pool theory holds that highly fractionalized systems are generally prone to increase
spending, and thus lead to an expansion of the welfare state, Primo and Snyder (2008)
argue that fractionalization can lead to lower spending. Intuitively, the benefits of smaller
and cheaper projects can be easier to internalize by specific groups, leading to lower overall
spending. For empirical evidence on the role of fractionalization, see, for example, Volkerink
and de Haan (2001).
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.
294 Does the welfare state destroy the family?
Our results indicate that a larger welfare state increases the turnover in
the marriage market by increasing both marriage and divorce rates. Because
the effect on marriage is stronger than that on divorce, an increase in the
size of the welfare state increases the stock of married individuals. Further,
we observe an increase in the fertility rate, which is particularly pronounced
for non-marital fertility (as compared to marital fertility). Hence, while
the welfare state supports the formation of families, it crowds out the
traditional organization of the family by increasing the divorce rate and
the number of children born out of wedlock. All the estimated effects are
highly statistically significant and their quantitative importance increases
when we use a narrower measurement of the welfare state.
Three guideposts can be used to put this analysis in the context of the
existing body of literature. First, we add to the literature that studies the
consequences of the welfare state in a general sense (Castles et al., 2010).
Second, we add to the literature on demographic trends (Stevenson and
Wolfers, 2007b).2With the exception of the out-of-wedlock ratio, compa-
rably little attention has been paid to the influence of the welfare state
on demographic outcomes.3In the public debate, the dominant view is
that the welfare state has to adjust to changing demographic patterns (as,
for instance, in the case of an aging society with extensive pensions sys-
tems). Our finding points to the reversed link, where the welfare state has
the capacity to shape demographic outcomes. Finally, we provide empiri-
cal support for Gary S. Becker’s claim that the organization of the family
changes as the state supplements or replaces traditional family functions.
In this regard, our empirical evidence complements the large body of liter-
ature examining the effects of specific US welfare arrangements on family
outcomes at less aggregated levels.4
Typically, scholars use variations in welfare benefit levels across time
and states to identify the effects on family outcomes. By and large, micro
analyses confirm theoretical expectations. Moffitt (1997) concludes that
many existing studies find a negative effect of public transfers on marriage,
2Economic scholars have studied the role of the economic independence of women (Isen
and Stevenson, 2011), access to abortion and oral contraception (Akerlof et al., 1996; Goldin
and Katz, 2000, 2002), changes in divorce law (Rasul, 2006; Wolfers, 2006; Matouschek
and Rasul, 2008), and reforms of custody law (Halla, 2013).
3A notable exception is Bj¨
orklund (2006) who identifies a positive effect of the Swedish
family policy on the overall fertility level.
4Earlier papers evaluate the effect of Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) and
more recent papers look at Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF). In the case
of AFDC, where the disposable income of recipients increases with children and decreases
with marriage, one expects a decrease in marriage, an increase in divorce, and an increase
in fertility, especially out of wedlock (Becker, 1993). TANF replaced AFDC (in 1996) and
reversed some of the incentives of welfare arrangements. In fact, the major stated goals of
this legislation included reducing out-of-wedlock births and increasing marriage.
CThe editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT