Court Efficiency and Procurement Performance

AuthorDecio Coviello,Paola Valbonesi,Giancarlo Spagnolo,Luigi Moretti
Published date01 July 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12225
Date01 July 2018
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.
Scand. J. of Economics 120(3), 826–858, 2018
DOI: 10.1111/sjoe.12225
Court Efficiency and Procurement
Performance*
Decio Coviello
HEC Montr´eal, Montr´eal, QC H3T 2A7, Canada
decio.coviello@hec.ca
Luigi Moretti
Panth´eon-Sorbonne University (Paris I), FR-75013 Paris, France
luigi.moretti@univ-paris1.fr
Giancarlo Spagnolo
Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE), SE-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden
giancarlo.spagnolo@hhs.se
Paola Valbonesi§
University of Padova, 35123 Padova, Italy
paola.valbonesi@unipd.it
Abstract
Disputes over penalties for breaching a contract are often resolved in court. A simple
model illustrates how inefficient courts can sway public buyers from enforcing a penalty
for late delivery in order to avoid litigation, thereby inducing sellers to delay contract
delivery. By using a large dataset on Italian public procurement, we empirically study the
effects of court inefficiency on public work performance. Where courts are inefficient,
we find the following: public works are delivered with longer delays; delays increase
for more valuable contracts; contracts are more often awarded to larger suppliers; and
a higher share of the payment is postponed after delivery. Other interpretations receive
less support from the data.
Keywords: Court efficiency; delay; enforcement cost; litigation; performance in contract
execution; public procurement; time incentives
JEL classification:H41; H57; K41
*Our thanks go to the three anonymous referees, to seminar participants at the “Procurement
and Corruption” workshop at the Toulouse School of Economics, the chair EPPP in Paris, the
Italian Society of Law and Economics, the “Public Procurement: Current Research Trends”
workshop in Moscow, the Pantheon-Sorbonne University (Paris 1), the ISNIE conference,
the conference of the French Economic Association, the EEA conference in Gothenburg,
and the National Research University Higher School of Economics in Perm, as well as to
A. Bennardo, R. Borsari, A. Estache, R. Camboni Marchi Adami, M. Colombo, C. Desrieux,
M. Klien, E. Iossa, S. Litschig, F. Lopez de Silanes, A. Meggiolaro, M. Moszoro, A. Nicol`o,
C. Pagliarin, E. Podkolzina, S. Rizzuto, S. Saussier, A. Shleifer, C. Staropoli, and S. Tadelis
for their comments. Valbonesi and Moretti gratefully acknowledge the financial support of
D. Coviello et al. 827
I. Introduction
Explicit contracting is a crucial governance instrument for public
procurement transactions. Concerns about accountability severely limit
civil servants’ discretion and, with it, the scope for relational contracting
(Kelman, 2002; Spagnolo, 2012). Similarly, reputational considerations
based on non-verifiable performance are rarely allowed in public
procurement.1However, contract enforcement costs can be significant
where the law court system is inefficient (Djankov et al., 2003).
Contracting parties can then choose ex post not to exercise their
contractual rights to save on enforcement costs. In public procurement,
high enforcement costs can therefore imply that buyers are unable to
effectively control suppliers’ opportunism.
In this paper, we study whether suppliers are more prone to opportunistic
behavior in public procurement when courts are less efficient. We
specifically focus on suppliers’ opportunism with regard to delivery delays.
As Lewis and Bajari (2011) stress, delivery time is often an important
quality dimension, and delays can have a significant negative impact on
end users. We first develop a stylized model in the spirit of the nuisance
claim literature (Rosenberg and Shavell, 1985) to organize the data and
guide the empirical analysis. The model also helps our understanding of
the incentives of the agents (i.e., suppliers and public buyers) involved
in the procurement process. The effects of trial duration on procurement
delays is a priori ambiguous and can depend on “who is suing who” (i.e.,
on who is the plaintiff and who is the defendant), and on other features
specific to the institutional environment such as litigation costs and their
distribution. In the Italian case, it is the contractor that must act as a
plaintiff because the contracting authority can move first by subtracting
the penalty from the contract. Under this assumption, and others chosen
to match the institutional setting from which our data originate, we derive
testable predictions relevant to the empirical analysis.
We then use a large dataset on public works collected by the Italian
Public Procurement Authority (henceforth, AVCP) for the years 2000–2006
the Italian Ministry of Education, University and Research (grant PRIN2008PYFHY/02) and
the University of Padova (grant no. CPDA084881/08);Spagnolo thanks the Swedish Research
Council (Vetenkapradet);and Coviello thanks the Canada Research Chairs program for financial
support.
Also affiliated with Centre d’Économie de la Sorbonne, University Paris 1.
Also affiliated with EIEF; University of Rome “Tor Vergata”; CEPR.
§Also affiliated with National Research University Higher School of Economics, Moscow.
1This has been particularly true in Europe, where reputational considerations have typically
been seen by legislators as a tool to discriminate against foreign suppliers (e.g., EC Directives
2004/17, 2004/18, 2014/24, and 2014/25); see Butler et al. (2013) for further discussion on
recent EU regulations.
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.
828 Court efficiency and procurement performance
to empirically investigate this relationship. AVCP maintains a centralized
electronic database containing a wide range of detailed information on
public procurement – crucial to our analysis and to any anti-corruption
activity – that are not even collected in the vast majority of other countries.
We merge this dataset with information collected by the Italian Statistics
Institute (henceforth, ISTAT) on the duration of civil trials by province
for each year. Our focus is Italy, which represents a unique laboratory for
studying the costs of an inefficient judiciary among developed countries.
Italy is a judicial outlier, twice as slow as any other member of the
OECD and characterized by large territorial and time variability in judicial
efficiency (Palumbo et al., 2013).
Our empirical findings suggest, as predicted by our model, that delays
in executing public works are positively associated with the duration of
civil trials. This effect is statistically significant, and it is robust to the
inclusion of a large set of contract, geographical, and time controls in
our regressions. We also find that the association between procurement
and court delays is stronger for larger and more complex projects. This
is also consistent with our model: as highlighted in the influential paper
by Bajari and Tadelis (2001), the more asymmetric information typical
of large/ complex contracts favors contractors in legal disputes.
Furthermore, we find that where trials take longer, contracts are more
often awarded to larger suppliers; this is in line with previous evidence
provided by Laeven and Woodruff (2007). We also find that the final
amount to be paid upon delivery is larger where the trial duration is
longer, a result which suggests that the public buyer attempts to reduce
the incentive to delay by increasing the supplier’s financial cost.
Finally, we consider different explanations and extensions of our results
on delivery delays, including corruption and public buyers’ fiscal restraints.
We find that our results are robust across model specifications and sample
selections.
Our paper relates to three main strands of economic literature. First, we
consider recent works on time incentives in public procurement contracts.
In particular, Lewis and Bajari (2011) theoretically and empirically
investigated an innovative procurement-awarding design adopted by the
California Department of Transportation that provides for explicit time
incentives. They estimate the benefits, in terms of social welfare, of
including project completion time in the auction mechanism. D’Alpaos
et al. (2013) developed a model in which – if penalties for late delivery are
included in the contract – the supplier’s choice concerning the execution
time can be investigated as a real option (i.e., a put option); in such a
setting, the supplier’s choice is affected by the volatility of investment
costs and by the enforcement of penalty clauses. Lewis and Bajari (2014)
investigated how higher penalties for delivery delays can induce greater
©The editors of The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT